[Created: 4 September, 2022]
[Revised: 1 August, 2023 ] |
In addition to the main text of the paper we have included three appendices:
At this website we have PDFs of the main works of the following key members of the Paris School:
As well as the following important texts:
Because of the large number of texts mentioned I have not created links to individual texts on this website. Please consult the accompanying bibliography of the works of members of the "Paris School" which are available online at this website, along with papers and other material I have written: "The Paris School of Political Economy": Summary and Overview, Key Institutions and Major Publications, Key People and Texts, My Essays and Blog Posts.
(E)n général on gouverne trop … (mais) comment s’y prendre pour simplifier une machine administrative compliquée où les intérêts privés ont gagné du terrain sur l’intérêt public, comme une gangrène qui s’avance dans un corps humain lorsqu’elle n’est pas repoussée par le principe de vie qui tend à le conserver ?. Pour guérir cette maladie il faut observer comment s’étend la gangrène administrative. Tout homme qui exerce un emploi tend à augmenter l’importance de ses fonctions, soit pour faire preuve d’un zèle qui lui procure de l’avancement, soit pour rendre son emploi plus nécessaire et mieux payé, soit pour exercer plus de pouvoir, augmenter le nombre des personnes obligées d’avoir recours à lui et de solliciter sa bienveillance. Le remède doit suivre une marche contraire et tendre à diminuer les attributions. |
In general we are governed too much ... (but) how do we go about reducing the size of a complicated administrative machine where private interests have gained ground over the public interest, like a gangrene which advances in a human body if it is not rejected by the life force which tends to protect it? To cure this disease we have to observe how the administrative gangrene is spread. Every person who is employed (by the state) tends to exaggerate the importance of his functions, whether this is to prove his zeal which will get him promoted, or to make his job (seem) more necessary and (thus) get paid more, or to exercise more power and (thus) increase the number of people who are obliged to come to him to sollicite his goodwill. The cure has to follow an opposite path and has to tend towards reducing the number of (their) duties. |
The uniqueness and importance of the "Paris School" of political economy has only recently (2006) got the attention it deserves. The late Michel Leter [2] has meticulously reconstructed the membership of its three generations who were active during the nineteenth century. [3] It was a coherent school of thought with a dense network of personal relationships which were mediated through several institutions and organisations based in Paris and which exerted considerable influence in the mid- and late-nineteenth century. This paper will discuss the emergence of the Paris School in the early years of the nineteenth century and its consolidation over three generations of thinkers into a coherent school of economic and social thought some 50 years later. The beginning and end points for the discussion are 1803, when Jean-Baptiste Say published the first edition of his Traité d'économe politique and the appearance of Guillaumin's Dictionaire de l"économie politique (1852-53) some fifty years later.
Before Leter, the Austrian economist Murray Rothbard in his history of economic thought (1995) gave due recognition to what he called "the French Smithians" led by J.B. Say which gradually evolved into "the French laissez-faire school" with Frédéric Bastiat as "the central figure." [4] At the time, the Parisian economists were content to call themselves simply "les Économistes" just as the Physiocrats had done the previous century. Hence, the title of their journal founded in 1841 by Guillaumin, "Journal des économistes" (Journal of THE Economists). It only gradually occurred to some of them to call themselves a particular school of thought as the 1840s wore on, when a number of them came to appreciate the "Frenchness" of their way of looking at economics, as opposed to the English classical school founded by Smith, Malthus, and Ricardo, and their followers in France. This was at first implied with the inclusion of a preponderance of French authors in the 15 volume Collection des Principaux Économistes edited by Eugène Daire beginning in 1840 (of the 15 volumes 10 were by French authors and 5 by the Anglo-Scottish authors Smith, Malthus, Ricardo). In his introductory essay to the volume with works by the late 17th century economist Boisguilbert (1843) Daire claimed that the economists of his day were the most recent "links in the chain of knowledge" which began with Boisguilbert and then moved on to Quesnay, Smith, JBS, Malthus, Ricardo, and finally Rossi. Making French economists like Boisguilbert, Quesnay, J.-B. Say, and Rossi coequals of Smith, Malthus, and Ricardo is a claim no member of the English classical school would ever have made. [5]
The realisation that the Paris economists were not just an offshoot of the Anglo-Scottish school, but something sui generis, became explicit when a small group began to break away from English orthodox thinking on the role of the state (Molinari), central banking (Coquelin), Smithian labour theory of value (Bastiat), Ricardian rent theory (Bastiat), and Malthusian population theory (Bastiat and Fontenay). Bastiat, for instance, came to realise he owed more of his intellectual development to another school of thought, "cette école éminemment française" (this eminently French school), of Say, Destutt de Tracy, Charles Comte, and especially Charles Dunoyer (whom he had read as a youth) than to "l"école de Malthus et de Ricardo" (the school of Malthus and Ricardo), or what his friend Roger de Fontenay rather dismissively called "cette école anglaise" (this English school). [6]
Although Bastiat did not go on to form a school of his own, as Fontenay had hoped, he was recognised by later members of the Paris School as one of its leading members for his contributions to both economic reform and theory. When one of the members of the third generation of the Paris School, Frédéric Passy (1822-1912), was asked by the Swiss Christian Society of Social Economy in 1890 to give a lecture on what they called "L"École de la Liberté" (the School of Liberty) as part of a month long program of lectures reviewing the state of political economy in the French speaking world at the end of the nineteenth century [7] what he gave was, in effect, a kind of requiem for the "Paris School" which he defended before a hostile audience of socialists and other interventionists. Passy acknowledged the importance of Bastiat in his conclusion by calling him "the most brilliant and purest representative of the doctrine of liberty."
The Paris School was by no means monolithic in its thinking and had to contend with several sub-currents which flowed within it, as well as countering criticism of its ideas from competing schools outside. Within, it was based upon two different intellectual foundations. The older, home-grown thread which came from the Franco-Physiocratic school or what might be termed "the precursors" of Pierre de Boisguilbert (1646-1714), [8] Richard Cantillon (1680-1734), [9] François Quesnay (1694-1774), [10] Étienne Bonnot de Condillac (1714-80), [11] and Turgot (1727-81). [12] Equally important was the Anglo-Scottish thread of Adam Smith (1723-1790), Jeremy Bentham (1748-1832), Thomas Malthus (1766-1858), and David Ricardo (1772-1823). [13]
Members of the Paris School, with the financial backing of Guillaumin, spent a lot of time rediscovering and promoting their diverse intellectual roots as the work of Adolphe Blanqui (1798–1854) and Eugène Daire (1798–1847) in our period reveal. And it would be done again fifty years later by Maurice Block. [14] One of the first three books ever published by the Guillaumin firm when it opened in 1837 was Blanqui's Histoire d'économie politique en Europe (1837) which was part history of economic thought and part economic history of Europe which went back to the ancient Greeks. It remained in print as long as Guillaumin lived, going through four editions. Guillaumin must have also invested heavily in one of the most ambitious publishing projects of the firm which saw in only its fourth year of operation the publication of the first volume of what would become 16 very large volumes called the Collection des Principaux Économistes under the editorship of Daire. It brought together in print the two threads mentioned above in a dramatic and striking visual way - 16 large volumes, with a total of 11,000 pages of classic texts and new notes by the editors, which could be purchased as a hardcover set for 200 fr. Guillaumin would do the same in its next big publishing project, the Dictionnaire de l"économie politique (1852) which would also have the history of economic thought as a core component.
It is interesting to speculate why they placed so much importance on their intellectual heritage. Several reasons come to mind: they might want to show that free market ideas were not an "English import" but had deep roots in France going back to the 17th century; that there was a long tradition of thinking about economic theory and that this body of thought was a "science" like any other; and that their intellectual forebears had overcome political and other obstacles (the persecution of Boisguilbert by Louis XIV comes to mind) just as they were trying to do in their own time. However, I believe the major reason is that they wanted to show, as Daire eloquently put it in his remark about the "links in the chain of knowledge" that this French tradition continued up to their own day. Yet, how these two intellectual foundations could be reconciled with each other was a constant source of debate during our period. The thread of Boisguilbert-Turgot-Condillac-Say sometimes clashed with the so-called "classical" thread of Smith-Malthus-Ricardo, especially the latter's notions of value, rent, and population, as the revisionist work of Bastiat in the mid-1840s would show.
Upon these foundations the early members of the Paris School such as Jean-Baptiste Say (1767-1832), Destutt de Tracy (1734-1836), and Charles Dunoyer (1786-1862), began doing their own innovative work on the entrepreneur, the nature of markets, and the new "industrialist" society which was emerging before their eyes. By the 1840s the school had matured into a well-organised group with its own journals, associations, a publishing firm, and contacts which extended well into the broader political and intellectual life of Paris. The main figures at this time were the publisher Gilbert Guillaumin (1801-1864) whose firm provided a locus for the school's activities, Adolphe Blanqui (1798-1854), Eugène Daire (1798-1847), Charles Coquelin (1802-1852), and Michel Chevalier (1806-1879). Its main focus was on ending the policy of trade protection and then countering the rise of socialism in the 1848 Revolution.
The school was also developing its own smaller group of "young Turks" (not all of whom were young in age) within it who began pushing the boundaries of the school into new and more radical directions until the outbreak of the February Revolution 1848 forced the entire school to change direction. This latter group of radicals and anti-statists consisted of Charles Coquelin (1802-1852), Gustave de Molinari (1819-1912), and Frédéric Bastiat (1801-1850), but their work was cut short through a combination of premature deaths and self-imposed exile from Paris following the rise to power of Louis Napoléon, soon to declare himself Napoléon III.
Outside the Paris School there were several schools of thought which were very hostile to their ideas and the policies based upon those ideas. This included an "Imperialist or Nationalist school" which supported protectionism and state support for favoured industries (Saint-Chamans, Ferrier, Lebastier, Lestisboudois); a "Social Reformist school", also known as the "Sentimentalist" school, which wanted the state to take a more active role in addressing "the social problem" of poverty and poor living conditions in the factories - this had a religious Catholic version (social Catholicism) (Villeneuve-Bargemont and later Le Play), a Sismondian version (Sismondi), and a liberal version (Lammenais, Montalembert); a "Socialist school" which had various diverse elements within it (Fourier, Blanc, Considerant, Proudhon); and a "Saint-Simonian school" which sought technocratic, state directed reforms and public works - with a free trade version (Chevalier) and a Napoleonic version (Louis Napoléon).
It should also be noted that, at the very end of our period, another school of thought began to emerge which had its roots partly at least in Paris, namely the thought of Karl Marx. He spent time in Paris in the mid and late 1840s, which was the heyday of the Paris School, where he met Friedrich Engels, researched and wrote The Economic and Philosophical Manuscripts (1844), and distributed the first copies of "The Communist Manifesto" (1848). Marx had minimal contact with members of the Paris School (discussed below) and his ideas were not known to the latter at this time.
In spite of differences between individual members of the Paris School there were some things they all by and large agreed upon. These included in general philosophical terms, a belief in individual liberty in both its political and economic dimensions, the right to self ownership and the right to own the things that this “self “ (le moi) was able to create or produce, and the right to trade one's justly owned property and services with others both domestically and internationally (free trade).
More specifically, when it came to political liberty they believed in freedom of speech, freedom of religion, freedom of association, representative government and a broader franchise, and the rule of law. Concerning economic liberty, they believed in private property, free markets, free trade, sound money, and low and more equally distributed taxes.
They also largely agreed on what they opposed. These included the following: protectionism and subsidies to industry, a state monopoly in education, state funding of churches, censorship, slavery, colonialism, conscription for the standing army, war, and socialism.
In spite of considerable agreement on many fundamental economic and political ideas, the school was divided over several key issues which they were never able to resolve, namely, republicanism vs. a constitutional monarchy, the number of public goods the government should provide, free banking, the cause of business cycles, and the extent of "tutelage" the government should provide for the poor and the ignorant and uneducated.
We can identify three generations of individuals who made up the Paris School, grouped according to when they were born and when they were most active. [15] The first generation of 13 individuals were born under the Old Regime and were active in the Empire (1803-1815) and the Restoration (1815-1830) when the first indications that a coherent school of thought began to emerge. It was in this early stage that we can see the first important productive period between 1815 and 1825 when a number of important books were published and innovative ideas were first introduced. The second generation of 26 individuals were born during the French Revolution and the First Empire and were active during the July Monarchy (1830-1848) and Second Republic (1848-1852). The 1830s was a difficult time for the school as it tried to rebuild itself after a number of deaths depleted their ranks, by working within the newly reconstituted Institute (1832) and creating their own organisations from scratch like the Guillaumin publishing firm (1837). The third generation of 23 individuals were born during the Restoration period and were active in the late July Monarchy and later in the century. The period from 1842 to 1852 saw the flowering or "take-off" of the school into a well organised, active, and productive group of very like-minded individuals. This decade was the second important period for the number of important books and new ideas which appeared by members of the school, culminating with the publication of the Dictionnaire de l"économie politique (1852-53). The "flowering" of the Paris school lasted until 1877 when a restructuring of the state university system erected serious impediments to the further expansion of the school, after which it went into a decline which lasted until the death of one of its last major figures, Yves Guyot (1843-1928).
C’est l’esprit de domination qui a formé ces agrégations monstrueuses ou qui les a rendues nécessaires; c’est l’esprit d’industrie qui les dissoudra: un de ses derniers, de ses plus grands et de ses plus salutaires effets paraît devoir être de municipaliser le monde. |
It is the spirit of domination which has formed these monstrous (political) agglomerations (agrégation), or which has made them necessary. It is the spirit of industry which will dissolve them; one of its last, greatest, and most salutary effects appears to have to be the municipalisation of the world. |
Sous son influence les peuples commenceront par se grouper plus naturellement; on ne verra plus réunis sous une même dénomination vingt peuples étrangers l’un à l’autre, disséminés quelquefois dans les quartiers du globe les plus opposés, et moins séparés encore par les distances que par le langage et les mœurs. Les peuples se rapprocheront, s’aggloméreront d’après leurs analogies réelles et suivant leurs véritables intérêts. … |
Under its influence, nations/people will begin by grouping together more naturally. We will no longer see united under the same name 20 peoples who are strangers to one another, sometimes dispersed to the four corners of the globe and opposed to each other more by language and customs than even by physical distance. People will draw closer to each other and gather together according to their real similarities and their true interests. … |
N’ayant plus mutuellement à se craindre, ne tendant plus à s’isoler, ils ne graviteront plus aussi fortement vers leurs centres et ne se repousseront plus aussi violemment par leurs extrémités. Leurs frontières cesseront d’être hérissées de forteresses; elles ne seront plus bordées d’une double ou triple, ligne de douaniers et de soldats. … |
No longer having to fear each other, no longer tending to be isolated from each other, they will no longer gravitate as strongly towards their centres and will no longer be so violently rejected by their (furthest) extremities. Their frontiers will cease bristling with fortresses, they will no longer be surrounded by a double or triple line of customs officers and soldiers. … |
Dans le même temps, une multitude de localités, acquérant plus d’importance, sentiront moins le besoin de rester unies à leurs capitales; elles deviendront à leur tour des chefs-lieux; les centres d’actions se multiplieront; et finalement les plus vastes contrées finiront par ne présenter qu’un seul peuple, composé d’un nombre infini d’agrégations uniformes, agrégations entre lesquelles s’établiront, sans confusion et sans violence, les relations les plus compliquées et tout à la fois les plus faciles, les plus paisibles et les plus profitables. |
At the same time, a multitude of places/localities, by acquiring more importance, will feel less need to remain united to their capital (city), they will become in their turn regional centres (chefs-lieux), these centres of activity will multiply, and finally the largest countries will end up by having (présenter = presenting to the world) only a single people/nation composed of an infinite number of similar/identical aggregations, between which will be established, without any confusion or violence, the most complex relations (which will be) at the same time the easiest, most peaceful, and most profitable ones (imaginable). |
Antoine-Louis-Claude Destutt de Tracy (1754–1836) |
Benjamin Constant (1767–1830) |
Jean-Baptiste Say (1767–1832) |
Charles Dunoyer (1786–1862) |
The first generation were born under the Old Regime and were active during the Empire and the Restoration. Its most important members [17] were the Ideologue theorist and politician Claude Destutt de Tracy (1754-1836); [18] the novelist, political theorist, and politician Benjamin Constant (1767-1830); [19] the journalist, politician, cotton manufacturer, and academic Jean-Baptiste Say (1767-1832); [20] the lawyer, journalist, and academic Charles Comte (1782-1837); [21] and the lawyer, journalist, academic, and politician Charles Dunoyer (1786-1862). [22]
The school's focus initially was on addressing the disruptions caused by the conquest and occupation of Europe by Napoléon's armies, the internal costs of raising mass armies (the "levée en masse" and conscription) and putting the French economy onto a war footing and the bureaucratic and regulatory means to do this, the number of deaths caused by war and disease, the disruption to trade caused by waging economic warfare against England by imposing a blockade on English imports into Europe (the Continental Blockade), Napoleon's undoing of many liberal economic reforms introduced in the early years of the Revolution, the establishment of the Bank of France to finance the war, and the censorship of critics of the régime (including economists like Tracy and Say, and the journalists Comte and Dunoyer).
They faced a second series of issues when Napoleon was defeated militarily and politically and the Bourbon monarchy was restored to power. The end of the wars brought several years of post-war economic depression as European economies adjusted to the new conditions of peace after 25 years of war and upheaval. The restoration was not only of the Bourbon monarchy, but also of the powers of the nobility, the large landowners, the established Church, and the traditional military. In particular they witnessed the restoration of high tariffs as part of a renewed alliance between the large land owners and industrialists who benefited from the system of high tariffs which France traditionally had imposed upon the country.
The economists responded to these problems in a variety of ways. In terms of economic theory the two most important treatises which appeared in the early years were Destutt de Tracy's Traité d'économie politique (1811) which first appeared as volume 4 of Eléments d'idéologie (1803-1815, 1817–1818) and then as a stand alone volume in 1823; and Jean-Baptiste Say's Traité d’économie politique which went through multiple revisions and editions (1803, 1814, 1817, 1819, 1826). Not surprisingly, both had difficulties with Napoleon who opposed their strong defence of free trade and non-intervention in the economy. Say for instance refused to rewrite his Treatise under direct pressure from Napoleon to endorse his policies of protectionism and trade embargoes. He waited until Napoleon was preoccupied elsewhere in 1814 before issuing the second edition which if anything was even more free trade than the first. Destutt de Tracy suffered from Napoleon's wrath when the latter closed down the Institute's "Class of Moral and Political Sciences" in 1803 effectively depriving him of influence and boasted that he had coined the name "Idéologues" as a term of abuse to undermine their moral authority. Like Say, Tracy delayed the publication of his volume dealing with political economy until the fall of Napoleon.
Of all the many important things these two authors discussed in their treatises they agreed on a number of key issues which would have a profound impact on the Paris School. First, the idea that government intervention in the economy was an impediment to trade and to the growth of prosperity, as well as a violation of an individual's natural right to life, liberty, and property. This idea of individual and economic liberty was a foundational concept for the Paris School.
Secondly, that the Physiocrats were wrong to argue that only agriculture was a productive activity. Tracy argued that merchants for example were productive by making it possible for consumers to get the things that producers made. [23] Say argued that entrepreneurs played a key role in bringing together all the factors of production, distribution, and sales without with very little economic activity would take place. Both developed ideas about class that pitted a "productive" or "industrious" class against a "non-productive" or "idle" class which would have important ramifications for the development of a classical liberal theory of class and exploitation in which the Paris School played a vital role.
Thirdly, that it was not just "material goods" like food, cloth, or iron bars which were produced and exchanged but a whole raft of "non-material goods" such as the services of teachers, judges, and opera singers which also could be analysed from an economic perspective. Say in particular was a pioneer in this new way of thinking about what we would call "services" and his early followers Charles Comte and Charles Dunoyer spent considerable time trying to determine where to draw the line between "productive" suppliers of services (like that of an opera singer whose performances are voluntarily "purchased" by consumers) and "non-productive" or "parasitical" producers (like government employed bureaucrats or members of the armed forces who are payed with tax-payers" money whether they wanted those services or not).
Fourthly, that the exchange of goods and services was not just an aspect of society but, in Tracy's aptly chosen phrase, that society itself was "nothing but a succession of exchanges." [24] The implication of this idea was that there was not two separate entities that needed to be studied, "society" on the one hand and "the economy" on the other, but rather one entity which was permeated by interlocking political, social, and economic relationships - or a "social economy" if you will. The latter was Say's preferred name for the field of study in which he was engaged and regretted that fact that the older name "political economy" had become so entrenched it was now near immovable. [25]
With the onset of blindness and increasing age Tracy withdrew from doing more theoretical work. Say on the other hand kept rewriting and expanding his Treatise through five editions spanning thirteen years (1803-1826) doubling its size in the process, [26] writing an even larger work based upon his lectures which was aimed at a broader audience, the Cours complet d'économie politique pratique (1828-29), and several pioneering shorter works of popularisation of economic ideas. [27] It is most unfortunate that this key figure's Treatise still does not have a modern scholarly English edition and that the Cours complet has never been translated into English at all.
Say's new theory of "social economy" had a profound impact on two of the leading defenders of classical liberal political theory in the late Empire and early Restoration, Charles Comte and Charles Dunoyer, and also to a lesser but still very substantial degree on Benjamin Constant. [28] Comte and Dunoyer had trained as lawyers and had started a small circulation journal Le Censeur in June 1814 in which they denounced the strict censorship laws and disregard for constitutional limits on state power for which they ran afoul of the censors in both the late Napoleonic régime and the newly restored Bourbon monarchy. [29] By an irony of history, when their magazine was forced to close in September 1815 they spent their time defending themselves in court as well as reading the latest books which had been released. One of these was the second revised edition of Say's Treatise (1814) which hit the young lawyers like a bombshell, completely transforming their understanding of what liberal theory was or could be. When they re-opened their journal in February 1817 it was now called Le Censeur européen and was filled with very different kinds of articles dealing with reviews of Say's books, an analysis of the history and functions of the "productive classes" (les industrieux) which produced the wealth which made society possible, the exploitation of the "industrious class" by the "unproductive classes" (usually associated with the state or groups privileged by the state in some way), the inevitable resistance to this exploitation by the industrious classes which resulted in revolution (whether the English Revolution of the 17th century or the more recent French Revolution), and a whole new theory of the evolution of societies through various economic stages which culminated in the rise of a new stage of "industrialism" which France was now on the verge of entering. [30] This flurry of activity was the start of a research agenda which lasted the two scholars another 20 years and had an enormous impact on the the rising generation of French classical liberals (most notably Frédéric Bastiat).
The direct influence of Say's new interpretation is harder to identify in the case of Benjamin Constant (and also on the novelist Stendhal) [31] but one can also see Constant's liberalism moving in a new direction at this time which also increasingly addressed economic matters. We can see it in his essay De l’esprit de conquête et de l’usurpation (1814) (with references to industry and commerce), in his famous lecture given at the Athénée royal de Paris on "De la liberté des anciens comparée à celles des modernes" (especially with his many references to the place of commerce in modern societies), the chapters dealing with economic matters in Les Principes de Politique (1806, 1815), in "De la liberté de l"industrie" (1818) in Collection complète (1818), and then in most detail in his long-forgotten Commentaire sur l’ouvrage de Filangieri (1822-24) (with his discussions of the privileged class and the rulers vs. the ruled). [32]
After Constant was elected to the Chamber of Deputies in March 1817 representing La Sarthe he was one of the few advocates for free trade when the matter came up for discussion in April and May 1821. The leading defenders of protectionism were Auguste Louis Philippe vicomte de Saint-Chamans (1777-1860), [33] who was a member of the Chamber of Deputies and the Council of State, and François-Louis-Auguste Ferrier (1777-1861), who had served as director general of the Customs Administration during the Empire. [34] They both gave fairly standard defenses of tariff protection and subsidies for domestic industry in the name of building a strong national economy. Benjamin Constant had been able to get appointed to the investigating committee which was headed by the wealthy land owner and royalist Deputy (Tarn) Marie-Joseph Dor de Lastours whose plan was to divide the country into 4 zones which would each have different regulations regarding what could or could not be imported or exported, to establish government financed grain storage depots to put aside surplus grain for periods of shortage, and to introduce a system of different sliding scales of prices for each zone which would trigger import bans or when the government would set prices for the sale of grain. The best the free traders like Constant could do was to amend the legislation so that the 12-15,000 largest landowners did not get all the spoils and that the interests of the other 6 million small land holders in France would get equal treatment. In a withering speech to the Chamber Constant declared himself to be “en état de défiance” (in a state of defiance) towards the government bill and clearly described the class interests which lay behind the measure. [35] Constant’s protests were in vain. The bill passed 282 to 54 on July 45, 1821 nearly doubling the rate of tariffs in some areas of France. However, following this spirited defense of free trade in the Chamber Constant wrote his one and only “treatise” on economics in the form of a lengthy commentary on the work of the Italian jurist Gaetano Filangieri which appeared in 1822 and contained a section on the benefits of free trade.
Returning to the fates of Charles Comte and Charles Dunoyer, after a series of arrests and trials Comte's activities as journalist were suspended in 1819 [36] and he was forced into exile to escape a two year prison sentence. He found refuge in Switzerland where he was able to secure a professorship in natural law at the University of Lausanne (1820-23) before pressure from the vengeful French government forced him to move to England (1823-26), where he met Jeremy Bentham and other members of the classical school of political economy. Comte eventually returned to Paris to turn his Swiss lectures on law and economics into the prize-winning book Traité de législation (1827) and its sequel Traité de la propriété (1834) in which he explored, among other things, the evolution of law and legal institutions, the nature and evolution of property, the class structure of slave societies and the nature of exploitation. [37]
Dunoyer on the other hand was able to remain in Paris and continued work as a journalist, author, and lecturer, publishing the first of a series of books on the evolution of the industrial stage of economic evolution, L"Industrie et la morale considérées dans leurs rapports avec la liberté (1825) which had been given as lectures at the Athénée, and then an expanded version Nouveau traité d'économie sociale (1830) with its obvious reference in the title to Say's preference for "social economy" over "political economy" as the proper field of study for his intellectual followers.
Say was more fortunate in that he was able to secure a couple of teaching positions in Paris at a time when there were very few such opportunities. He began giving lectures at the private educational institution the Athénée royal (where lectures were open to members of the public) in 1816 following the success of the second edition of his Treatise (1814) and the easing of censorship; he was granted a Chair of "Industrial Economics" (the name "political economy" was seen to be be too radical at the time) at the government funded Conservatoire national des arts et métiers (The National Conservatory of Technical Arts and Trades) in 1819 which he held to his death in 1832; and, being the entrepreneur that he was, he co-founded a private business school, l"École Spéciale de Commerce et d'Industrie (The School for Commerce and Industry) in 1819, where he also taught. When a dedicated chair of political economy was finally created in 1831 following the July Revolution of August 1830 Say was appointed to it but only served a year before he died in November 1832.
The content of these lectures has not been known in any detail until very recently. His Leçons d’économie politique (Lectures on Political Economy) given at the Athénée in 1819 and the Conservatoire between 1820-29 were finally published as part of his Œuvres complètes (2002). [38] They reveal a much more radical side to Say than appears in the printed Treatise and the Cours complet. Here Say seems to cut loose from the strictures imposed by the censors and appears at times to be moving towards the free market version of anarchism which Gustave de Molinari would advocate in 1849.
The rise of a small but vocal group of free traders like Say and Constant provoked a protectionist response, especially when the question of tariff reform came up in the Chamber for debate in 1821-22. At this stage the response by defenders of protectionism like Saint-Chamans and Ferrier, was not very sophisticated or urgent as the political challenge posed by the free traders was very weak as result of the very narrow electoral franchise which limited voting to the top 5% of tax payers who were large landowners and industrialists who benefited from tariffs. It would become much more intense 25 years later when tariff reform was discussed again in 1847 at a time when the French Free Trade movement had become organised under Bastiat's leadership and energised by the success of the free trade Anti-Corn Law League in England in 1846.
We can also see the beginnings of a more sophisticated socialist critique of liberal political economy beginning to emerge during the Restoration. It too would become powerful and threatening enough to absorb most of the Paris School's attention during the Second Republic, which would be the task of the Second and Third Generations of the Paris School to counter. One such thread was started by Sismondi, who began as a defender of free trade and free markets in De la richesse commerciale (1803) but began to have serious doubts during the economic depression which struck in the years following the end of Napoléon's Empire in 1815. In Nouveaux principes d'économie politique (1819) he expressed the view that perhaps the "capitalist system" had a built-in tendency to impoverish the poorest members of society who could not survive the rigours of competition or the threat of impoverishment caused by overpopulation without some government regulation. The Paris economists, on the other hand, saw these economic recessions as the result of what Bastiat would later call "les causes perturbatrices" (disturbing or disrupting factors) which were due to political interventions in the economy, not the operations of the free market itself. However, this thread of criticism of the free market introduced by Sismondi would persist and even grow stronger during the rest of the century.
A more fundamental critique of the ideas of the Paris School would come from the socialist movement which would develop into a formidable force by the mid-1840s and even take control of one part of the Provisional Government during the early months of the February Revolution of 1848. We can see the first stirrings of the Saint-Simonian school with the appearance of Saint-Simon's Du système industriel (1821) which was co-written by Augustin Thierry who had been a collaborator of Comte's and Dunoyer's on Le Censeur européen, becoming at one stage the editor while Comte and Dunoyer were in the courts fighting the censors. [39] There were some parallels between the theory of "industrialism" of the Comte/Dunoyer group and Saint-Simonians but they split over the question of the role of the state. The "liberal industrialists" wanted the state to adopt a policy of laissez-faire which would allow the productive industrial class to grow and prosper on their own, whereas the "interventionist industrialists" thought the state should guide this development through regulation and planning from the top down. The "interventionist industrialists" in turn split into a more free market group (the most important representative of which was the economist Michel Chevalier) and a socialist group which envisaged a very large and permanent role of the state in all future economic development.
The most thorough-going socialist critique to emerge at this time was Fourier"s, whose book Le Nouveau monde industriel et sociétaire (1829) was published at the very end of the Restoration. He envisaged a complete reorganisation of society both economically and socially with the total abolition of free markets and wage labour. People would "associate" together by living and working in large cooperatives known as "Phalanxes" where there would be no wages paid nor profits made, but all would share in doing the work and receiving the benefits. His ideas about "association" would join with Louis Blanc's ideas about "organisation" among workers to form the backbone of the socialist challenge to the Paris School's ideas in the late 1840s.
The first generation of the Paris School came to a figurative and some cases literal end with the overthrow of the the Bourbon monarchy by the Orléanist branch of the family under Louis Philippe in July 1830. Censorship, limited teaching possibilities, exile, and death had depleted their ranks and this weakness in the school would continue in the first few years of the July Monarchy until the Paris School could replenish its ranks with some new blood. They had enjoyed a flowering in the "long decade" between 1814 and 1827 which saw the publication of a revised edition of Say's Treatise (1814), Constant's Les Principes de Politique (1815), vol. 4 of Tracy's Eléments d'idéologie (1817), Dunoyer's L"Industrie et la morale (1825), and Comte's Traité de législation (1827).
Four of the leading figures in the first generation were old by the end of the Restoration and died soon afterwards. Constant died in 1830. Say in 1832, Tracy in 1836, and Charles Comte in 1837. They left a significant gap which would be hard to replace, but it was when a new generation of the Paris School emerged in the late 1830s and began to flourish in the early 1840s.
Dans la sphère économique, un acte, une habitude, une institution, une loi n’engendrent pas seulement un effet, mais une série d’effets. De ces effets, le premier seul est immédiat ; il se manifeste simultanément avec sa cause, on le voit. Les autres ne se déroulent que successivement, on ne les voit pas ; heureux si on les prévoit. Entre un mauvais et un bon Économiste, voici toute la différence : l’un s’en tient à l’effet visible ; l’autre tient compte et de l’effet qu’on voit et de ceux qu’il faut prévoir. |
In the sphere of economics an action, a habit, an institution, or a law engenders not just one effect but a series of effects. Of these effects only the first is immediate; it is revealed simultaneously with its cause; it is seen. The others merely occur successively; they are not seen; we are lucky if we foresee them. The entire difference between a bad and a good Economist is apparent here. A bad one relies on the visible effect, while the good one takes account both of the effect one can see and of those one must foresee. |
Frédéric Bastiat (1801–1850) |
Michel Chevalier (1806–1879) |
Joseph Garnier (1813–1881) |
Gustave de Molinari (1819–1912) |
Frédéric Passy (1822–1912) |
The gaps left by the passing of the first generation were filled by two new generations of economists who were active in the July Monarchy and the Second Republic, and their very productive period of intellectual activity was the decade between 1842 and 1852.
The second generation of the Paris School were born during the French Revolution and the First Empire, [41] the most important members of which were the book seller and publisher Gilbert Guillaumin (1801-1864); [42] the journalist, free trade activist, and politician Frédéric Bastiat (1801-1850); [43] the journalist, editor and advocate of free banking Charles Coquelin (1802-1852); [44] the academic Michel Chevalier (1806-1879); [45] and the academic and peace advocate Joseph Garnier (1813-1881). [46]
The third generation were born during the Restoration period [47] and its most important members who were old enough to have been active in this period were the journalist and academic Gustave de Molinari (1819-1912), [48] the young Ricardo scholar Alcide Fonteyraud (1822-1849), [49] and the politician, peace activist, and academic Frédéric Passy (1822-1912). [50]
Along with some longer lived members of the first generation, a sizable contingent of the Paris School was represented at various levels in the government. We can count three ministers, four Peers of France, 13 elected Deputies, four members of the General Council, five members of the Council of State, two Prefects of Departments, and two ambassadors. [51] For example, following the July Revolution of 1830 Charles Dunoyer entered government perhaps taking at face value the promises of Louis Philippe to introduce more of a constitutional monarchy and lift some of the worst excesses of censorship and limits on political associations which had been the hallmark of the final years of Charles X's reign. Dunoyer became Prefect of Allier, la Mayenne, and then la Somme, and was appointed a Councillor of State in 1838. [52] Frédéric Bastiat was rewarded for his support in August 1830 with the post of Justice of the Peace in his home town of Mugron in 1831 and then an appointment as a General Councillor in 1833 for whom he wrote a series of important economic monographs on tax reform. [53]
These liberal officials provided a voice in favour of many liberal reforms within the government but without an expanded electorate of supporters (as produced in England by the First Reform Act of 1832) they did not have the clout to push through those reforms in the face of the unbending opposition of Louis Philippe's various governments, as their failure to achieve any tariff reform after a government inquiry in the first half of 1847 proves. It soon became clear that the governments headed by François Guizot and Adolphe Thiers were royalist, elitist, and protectionist while many (though not all) members of the Paris School were republican, democratic, and laissez-faire in their inclinations. When the February Revolution opened the door to universal (manhood) suffrage the members of the Paris School were dismayed that the expanded franchise was more likely to vote for another Napoléon than they were to vote for free trade.
The rebuilding of the Paris School began with the recreation of the Institute by Louis Philippe in 1832 after its closure in 1803 by Napoléon in order to remove some of his harshest critics like Destutt de Tracy. Members of the Paris School were well represented in the new Institute's Academy of Moral and Political Sciences which was one of its five branches. The permanent secretary was Charles Comte and members included the following (with the year they were elected): Charles Dunoyer (1832); Joseph Droz (1832); Pellegrino Rossi (1836); Alexis de Tocqueville (1838); Hippolyte Passy (1838); Adolphe Blanqui (1838); Gustave de Beaumont (1841); Léon Faucher (1849); Louis Reybaud (1850); Michel Chevalier (1851); Louis Wolowski (1855); Horace Say (1857); Augustin-Charles Renouard (1861); Henri Baudrillart (1866); Joseph Garnier (1873); Frédéric Passy (1877); Léon Say (1881). Bastiat was made a more junior "corresponding member" in 1846 as was Molinari in 1877. [54]
A second innovation was the recognition by the new régime [55] of the discipline of "political economy" as being worthy enough to have its own Chair at the Collège de France. [56] It was created in 1831 and the first appointee was Jean-Baptiste Say who unfortunately did not have time to settle into the new position before he died in November the following year at the age of 65. This sparked a battle to decide upon his successor. The members of the Academy of Moral and Political Sciences supported their own more radical Charles Comte for the position, while the other professors at the Collège supported the more conservative Italian jurist Pellegrino Rossi who eventually got the position. [57] This was unfortunate as Rossi was neither an original thinker in economics nor very radical in his opinions, although he was a strong supporter of free trade.
Rossi held the position from 1833 to 1840 when he was replaced by the free market Saint-Simonian engineer and economist Michel Chevalier who held the post between 1841 and 1852. [58] However, Chevalier's career showed the precarious situation the economists were in when there we so few academic positions of any kind. Opponents of his free market views within the Provisional Government of the Second Republic had him sacked from his position in April 1848 and divided his chair into several smaller positons which dealt with more "applied economics" which were seen as being more useful for government employed bureaucrats and planners. Only after intense lobbying by the members of the Political Economy Society and their supporters in the National Assembly was Chevalier reappointed to his position in November 1848. Chevalier would make a name for himself as a fierce anti-socialist pamphleteer during 1848-49 and then later as a trusted economic advisor to Louis-Napoléon (Emperor Napoléon III after 1852) who persuaded him to fulfill the dreams of the Paris School by agreeing to sign the first free trade treaty between England and France in 1860, the formal signing of which was done by Richard Cobden for England and Chevalier for France.
There were only two other government funded institutions where members of the Paris School found teaching positions. These were the less prestigious, non-research positions in technical and engineering schools such as the Conservatoire national des Arts et Métiers (the National Conservatory of Technology and Trades) where where J.B. Say had taught "industrial economics" until his death in 1832 and then his replacement Adolphe Blanqui taught from 1833, [59] and the École nationale des Ponts et Chaussées (National School of Bridges and Roads) where Joseph Garnier was appointed a professor of political economy in 1846 when the first chair was established there.
Outside the state system there were a handful of private institutions where economists could teach, or at least give public lectures. Firstly, there was the well-established private lecture forum, the Paris Athénée, where J.B. Say had lectured in 1816-19, Charles Dunoyer 1824-26, Adolphe Blanqui 1827-29, and Joseph Garnier 1842-45. There was also the École Supérieure de Commerce de Paris (The Advanced School of Commerce), which was a private business school which had been co-founded by J.B. Say during the early years of the Restoration. Adolphe Blanqui was appointed director in 1830 and he worked there until his death in 1854. Joseph Garnier also taught there in the 1840s before he took up a position at the École nationale des Ponts et Chaussées. The School of Commerce played a particularly important role in helping establish the careers of two generations of political economists in the Paris School.
The teaching and research prospects for academic economists remained dire until the educational reforms of 1878 which resulted in the professionalisation and insititutionalisation of economics as an academic discipline. Unfortunately, for the members of the Paris School when the government of the new Third Republic decided to expand the teaching of economics they agreed to fund it only within the Law Faculties which required a doctorate in law which none of the economists had, thereby excluding them from the newly created posts. The end result was that economics was often taught by people untrained in economics and not inclined to support laissez-faire views, to students who would become lawyers, bureaucrats, and government officials, who were also disinclined to be receptive to free market ideas. [60]
This problem of the limited supply of teaching and research positions explains why the advent of the Guillaumin publishing firm in 1837 and the satellite associations it spawned afterwards is so important for understanding the growth of the Paris School in the 1840s.
[The Molière Fountain on the rue de Richelieu (down the left).
The Guillaumin firm was located at no. 14 rue de Richelieu.]
One of the most important innovations for the consolidation of the Paris School as a serious, organised, and influential intellectual movement came from the entrepreneurial activities of Gilbert-Urbain Guillaumin (1801-1864) who founded the publishing firm which bore his name in 1837. [61] He had become active in politics in the 1820s when he joined the radical democratic and republican Carbonari movement. This may explain his later support for some of the more radical members of the Paris School whose work the firm would later publish, such as Charles Coquelin, Frédéric Bastiat, and Gustave de Molinari, in spite of the objections of many of the more mainstream members of the school. The Guillaumin firm would become the focal point for the Paris School for the next 74 years, channelling money which he helped raise from wealthy benefactors (such as the merchant Horace Say (son of Jean-Baptiste) and the industrialist Casimir Cheuvreux) into the pockets of several generations of liberal political economists. The historian Gérard Minart correctly calls this “le réseau Guillaumin” (the Guillaumin network) given the number of individuals, groups, associations, and activities Guillaumin founded, financed, or put in touch with each other. [62]
The firm commissioned books on economics (publishing a total of 2,356 titles between 1837 and 1910 at an average rate of 31.8 titles per year), [63] began the Journal des Économistes in December 1841 (it lasted nearly 100 years until the Nazi occupation of Paris in 1940 forced it to close), [64] and the Société d'économie politique in 1842 which became the main organization which brought classical liberals, [65] sympathisers in the intellectual and political elites of France, and foreign visitors together for discussion and debate at their monthly dinner meetings, presided over by the Society's permanent president Charles Dunoyer.
The publishing strategy of the Guillaumin firm was a sophisticated one which proved to be very successful over many decades. It was designed to attract a broad range of authors as well as readers from different ideological perspectives, not just the hard core of radical laissez-faire advocates. It attracted businessmen with its first commercial success, an Encyclopédie du commerçant. Dictionnaire du commerce et des marchandises (A Dictionary of Commerce and Goods) (1837, 1839, 1841) [66] and other titles dealing with how to buy shares on the stock exchange, bankruptcy law, and trade marks. Its staple was the monthly Journal des Économistes [67] and the annual compendium of statistics and economic data Annuaire de l’économie politique et de la statistique (founded 1844) edited by Guillaumin and Joseph Garnier. [68]
On more theoretical matters, it published in book form the lectures given by Pellegrino Rossi, Michel Chevalier, and Joseph Garnier at the universities and colleges in order to give them a far greater audience. It published dozens of books on economic and financial history, especially on tax, government finance, and pubic credit. It published a steady stream of books dealing with poverty and the social question. A very large academic project it undertook in 1840 was to publish a large collection in 15 volumes of key works in the history of economic thought which was edited by a former tax collector turned editor Eugène Daire (1798-1847) which began by republishing the main works of J.B Say before turning to works on eighteenth-century finance, the physiocrats, Turgot, Adam Smith, Malthus, Ricardo, Hume, and Bentham. This project was notably also for its use of the young generation of rising economists like Alcide Fonteyraud and Gustave de Molinari as editors of some of the volumes, thus giving them much needed income as well as helping them make a name for themselves as scholars. [69]
Finally, they were also keen to demonstrate the new directions in which the Paris School was moving by publishing innovative works by some of the more radical members of the Guillaumin network, such as Coquelin, Du Crédit et des Banques (1848) on free banking, Molinari, Les Soirées de la rue Saint-Lazare (1849) on free market alternatives to public goods provided by the state, Bastiat, Harmonies économiques (1850, 1851), which was his controversial and in part proto-Austrian theoretical treatise, [70] and Ce que l"on voit et ce que l"on ne voit pas ou l"économie politique en une leçon (1850) which was a pioneering work using the idea of opportunity cost to argue against many forms of government expenditure and regulation.
In addition to the publishing firm there were several other groups and organisations which were part of the broader "Guillaumin network" of economists and their friends and allies. These included the French Free Trade Association, [71] the Congrès des Économistes, [72] the Friends of Peace Congress, [73] and the private Paris salons held by Anne Say (née Cheuvreux, the wife of the businessman Horace Say) and Hortense Cheuvreux (the wife the the wealthy textile manufacturer Casimir Cheuvreux). [74]
However, the pinnacle of the Paris School's achievement in this period was their compendium of "irrefutable" arguments and economic data which would answer all their protectionist, interventionist, and socialist critics - the Dictionnaire de l’économie politique (1852-53). [75] The DEP is a two volume, 1,854 page, double-columned encyclopedia of political economy and is unquestionably one of the most important publishing events in the history of 19th century French classical liberal thought and is unequalled in its scope and comprehensiveness. The aim was to assemble a compendium of the state of knowledge of liberal political economy with articles written by leading economists on key topics, biographies of important historical figures, annotated bibliographies of the most important books in the field, and tables of economic and political statistics. The Economists believed that the events of the 1848 Revolution had shown how poorly understood the principles of economics were among the French public, especially its political and intellectual elites. One of the tasks of the DEP was to rectify this situation with an easily accessible summary of the entire discipline. The major contributors were the editor Charles Coquelin (with 70 major articles), Gustave de Molinari (29), Horace Say (29), Joseph Garnier (28), Ambroise Clément (22), Courcelle-Seneuil (21), and Maurice Block wrote most of the biographical entries. The intellectual ghost floating over the entire project was the recently deceased Frédéric Bastiat. If his health had not been failing rapidly he might have been expected to have played a major role in its production. The editor Coquelin paid homage to him by using large chunks of Bastiat's essays for two of the key entries in the DEP on "The State" and "The Law."
Sadly, as the century was coming to a close and as classical liberal ideas were becoming less and less influential, the Guillaumin firm tried to repeat the exercise with an updated version of the DEP in 1891, interestingly edited by Jean-Baptiste Say's grandson Léon, but with little obvious success in halting the tide of opinion. [76]
The economic and political issues the economists had to deal with after 1830 were dominated by the issues of poverty and "the social question" in newly industrialising France, reform of the protectionist system of tariffs and subsidies to industry, and the rise of socialism both as a body of thought as well as an increasingly organised political movement.
It is often assumed that the problem of poverty was discovered in the 1830s by religiously inspired social reformers, like Villeneuve-Bargemont's Économie politique chrétienne (1834), or liberal-minded conservatives, like Tocqueville's Mémoire sur le paupérisme (1833) who feared state charity would create a permanent underclass of the poor, and by socialists like Louis Blanc's Organisation du travail (1839) who saw poverty as the proof of the failure of free markets. But this would be incorrect. In should be noted in passing that the future Emperor Napoléon III wrote a pamphlet while in prison, Extinction du Paupérisme (1844), on how to solve the problem of "pauperism" by converting the unused land in France into "agricultural colonies" where labour would be organised along Blanc's suggestions by "labour marshalls" ("les prudhommes") who would act as state-financed intermediaries between the workers and the employers. [77]
In the early and mid-1840s the Guillaumin firm published a dozen or so books on this question which indicates their strong interest in the matter, such as d'Esterno, De la Misère, de ses causes, de ses remèdes (1842); A. Clément, Recherches sur les causes de l’indigence (1846); Théodore Fix, Observations sur l’état des classes ouvrières (1846); and Joseph Garnier, Sur l’association, l’économie politique et la misère (1846), to mention only a few. Where they differed from the social Catholics and the socialists was in the reforms they proposed to solve the problem, not in the fact that they ignored the problem or didn"t take it seriously.
They agreed with the former that there was a need for more charity but only as long as it was charity which was voluntarily given and not "la charité légale" (state funded or "coerced" charity). They agreed with the latter that the current system was broken and did not serve the best interests of the workers, but not that the free market system of wage labour should be abolished and replaced by socialist schemes of industrial "organisation" and labour "associations," something which would in fact be tried by Louis Blanc in the National Workshops program after February 1848. Instead, they wanted to see all restrictions on the free movement of labour (the right to enter any job or industry without restriction), of capital (the right to set up factories and businesses anywhere and at any time), and of goods (international and domestic free trade) lifted so that all workers could reap the benefits of the division of labour and open markets. One of the things that Chevalier admired most about the United States was the freedom ordinary workers had to mover about the country and enter any occupation they wished without having to seek the permission of the government. [78] He thought that similar freedoms in France would go a long way to solving the social question.
They all agreed, however, in the pessimistic conclusions of Thomas Malthus that excessive population growth led to cut throat competition between workers and thus lower wages, unless they exercised the "moral restraint" required to limit the size of their families. Most members of the Paris School were convinced Malthusians, with Joseph Garnier being the leading Malthusian with several books and articles on his ideas. He edited Guillaumin's edition of Malthus’s Essai sur le principe de population (1845) and wrote the entries on "Population" and "Malthus" for the DEP (1852). [79] Interestingly, for this the Catholic Church regarded the Economists and the DEP (1852-53) as grossly immoral and had it listed on the Index of Banned Books on 12 June 1856 for “religious reasons.” [80]
One of the few exceptions to this support for Malthus was Bastiat who rejected the idea that the poor were condemned to hovering just above or just below the biological means of subsistence. He preferred to think in terms of the "means of existence" or "standard of living" of a society, which was not a set amount but moved steadily upwards as the economy progressed. The productivity of the free market, if it were unshackled from its protectionist chains and high levels of taxation, would dramatically raise the standard of living of all people, including the poorest. Furthermore, he rejected the idea that mankind's reproductive behavior was like that of an unthinking plant or an animal (which were subject to Malthusian population traps) but was the result of thinking and reasoning human beings who could adapt their behaviour to changing circumstances. He completely rethought Malthus" population theory in an an article on "Population” for the JDE (October 1846) and in a revised version in a chapter in Economic Harmonies (the expanded second edition of 1851). He was vigorously challenged by the other members of the Paris School who were unmoved by his arguments and they remained staunch Malthusians for the rest of the century.
The reason the economists were so hostile to tariffs and other subsidies to industry can be reduced to three main points. Firstly, they saw it as a violation of the property rights of producers and consumers, no matter what country they lived or worked in, to buy and sell their goods and services without interference from third parties. To impose a tax or tariff or to prohibit the entry of goods was, in Bastiat's very direct terminology a form of "legal plunder" [81] and should not be allowed on moral grounds. Secondly, they saw tariffs as just another tax imposed upon the poor, especially on essentials such as food and clothing and, since this is France after all, on wine. It was also a tax imposed on small business owners who ran their own shop or workshop and had to pay taxes on imported raw materials they used to make their own products for sale. Thirdly, they saw the beneficiaries of tariffs and subsidies very much in class terms, where wealthy landowners and industrialists who cloaked their own self-interest in eliminating competitors and increasing their profits in terms of "protecting national labour", were in fact part of an "oligarchy" or "privileged class" who exploited ordinary consumers for their own benefit. [82] This combination of moral, economic, and political arguments explains the Paris School's passion in opposing tariffs which they maintained over many decades.
There were three occasions after 1815 when tariff reform was seriously debated in the Chamber of Deputies. [83] The first was in 1821 during the Restoration (discussed above), the second was in 1831-33 soon after the installation of the July Monarchy, and the third was in 1847 on the eve of the 1848 Revolution. Only in the latter case was there a serious chance of any liberalization since the free trade movement which had emerged in 1846 was stronger than it had been at any time previously in the 19th century.
An opportunity for tariff reform presented itself following the poor harvests of 1828-29 and the overthrow of the Bourbon Monarchy in August 1830 which brought to power the July Monarchy of Louis Philippe. Intellectually the classical liberal movement during the 1830s was at a low point since several of them who had come to prominence during the Empire and the Restoration were either quite old or would soon die. The new government commissioned an inquiry into tariff policy in October 1831 with the naval engineer and statistician Charles Dupin (1784-1873) as the head. [84] After five months of deliberation a very lengthy report was produced which was even more protectionist than the government’s original proposal. This was opposed in the Chamber by a small group of free traders who gathered around the journalist and politician Prosper Duvergier de Hauranne (1798-1881), [85] the liberal minded aristocrat Alexandre De Laborde (1773-1842), and François-Eugène, duc d’Harcourt (1786-1865) who later became one of the founders of the Free Trade Association in 1846. The bill was discussed in March 1832 and provisionally adopted until it was made permanent in April 1833. The passage of this bill was a disaster for the depleted and weakened free trade group within the Chamber. The French free trade movement at this time was so weak that the most vigorous response came from an English free trader Thomas Perronet Thompson (1783-1869) who wrote an amusing but thorough critique of the inquiry (in French) called Contre-Enquête: par l’Homme aux Quarante Ecus (A Counter-Inquiry by a Man on 40 Ecus a Year) (1834). This period would have to count as the nadir of the French free trade movement in the first half of the 19th century.
The stimulus for a third attempt at tariff reform came from the activities of the Anti-Corn law League founded in 1838 in Manchester by the manufacturer Richard Cobden and John Bright. Its success in mobilizing popular support for free trade came to the attention of Bastiat in 1844 while he was still living in the relative seclusion of Gascony in the southwest of France. He began subscribing to their journals and other literature and published a lengthy account of their philosophy and most importantly their strategy in Cobden et la Ligue (1845) which erupted like an intellectual bombshell in France. Bastiat wrote a lengthy introduction describing the League’s principles and their critique of British economic policy, translated dozens of speeches and articles by advocates of the free trade position, and described at considerable length how they went about organising a mass movement in favour of free trade, including the important role women played in organising the meetings and handing out literature. Cobden and Bright cleverly made use of the expanded franchise after the 1832 electoral reforms and invented many of the modern methods of organising popular opinion such as collecting signatures to present to politicians, selling merchandise to raise money, organising a travelling band of public speakers who would tour the country talking to large crowds in public halls, and keeping their paid members abreast of affairs with a regular newspaper.
This was the first salvo in a battery of intellectual shells which the new generation of economists lobbed onto the French public between 1845 and 1847 which dramatically changed the debate about tariffs. The salvo included books by the journalist and member of the Chamber of Deputies Léon Faucher (1803-54) who wrote Études sur l’Angleterre (1845) which had two chapters on the Anti-Corn Law League and provided comprehensive background information about the British economy, London, Liverpool and Manchester, and the social and economic reasons behind the rise of Anti-Corn Law League; a series of eight detailed articles by the fluent English speaker Alcide Fonteyraud (1822-1849) who had been sent to England with a letter of introduction to Richard Cobden by Frédéric Bastiat to gather information on the Anti-Corn Law League; [86] the republication by Guillaumin of speeches and essays by an early supporter of free trade in Bordeaux during the 1830s, Henri Fonfrède, Du système prohibitif (1846) possibly in an attempt to show that free trade ideas were not just an English import; the publication of a series of speeches in support of free trade given in the Chambers of Deputies and Peers by the duc d’Harcourt in 1845 and 1846 who was the leading free trader in the Chamber and who became the President of the French Free Trade Association when it was founded in July 1846; [87] a second book on Cobden and the League this time by the economist Joseph Garner in 1846 to follow on from Bastiat’s pioneering work the previous year; [88] a pair of articles by the aging doyen of the Paris School, Charles Dunoyer; [89] and finally Molinari’s comprehensive 2 volume History of Tariffs in 1847 which established his reputation as a serious and rising economist. [90]
Following the success of Bastiat’s and Faucher’s books and the duc d’Harcourt’s speech in the Chamber in 1845, as well as the climax of the British Anti-Corn Law League’s efforts to have the Corn Laws repealed which was announced in the Commons by Sir Robert Peel on January 27 1846, an “Association de la liberté des échanges” (Free Trade Association) was founded in Bordeaux in February 1846 and then a national Association in Paris in July. The duc d’Harcourt was the President of the Association, Bastiat was Secretary General, and Molinari along with Adolphe Blaise, Charles Coquelin, Alcide Fonteyraud, Joseph Garnier were Associate Secretaries, and other founding members and advisors included Michel Chevalier, Auguste Blanqui, and Horace Say. Bastiat wrote the "Statement of Principles" of the Society which contained the radical claim that free trade was a natural right "just like property" which is held by all human beings. [91] The first public meeting of the Paris Association for Free Trade was held in Montesquieu Hall on August 28, 1846 which was the first of a series of public meetings and appeals to the public for support along the lines of the strategy which had been used by the British Anti-Corn Law League. One of their best public speakers was Charles Coquelin who used his deep knowledge of French literature and economic theory to great effect. Another star speaker was the famous poet and politician Alphonse Lamartine who drew very large crowds to hear him deliver his witty and eloquent speeches. [92] As secretary of the Association and editor of its journal Le Libre-Échange Bastiat spent much of 1846 and 1847 travelling all over France giving speeches in Marseilles, Lyon, Bordeaux, and of course Paris.
Many of the articles Bastiat wrote for Le Libre-Échange were collected and republished in two volumes as Economic Sophisms which sold very well for the Guillaumin firm. They were designed for a popular audience and often took the form of a reductio ad absurdum argument where he would take an argument of the protectionists, such as the need to create more work for French workers, which Bastiat suggested could be achieved if the government ordered every French worker to only use their left hand - “The Right Hand and the Left Hand” (LE, 13 Dec. 1846). His most famous "sophism" was the fictional “Petition by the Manufacturers of Candles, etc.” (JDE, October 1845) in which he ridiculed the industrialists who lobbied the government to pass laws to make consumers buy their higher priced goods instead of cheaper imports. In this case, candle manufacturers who wanted the government to pass laws forcing everybody to pull their house shutters closed during the day so they would have to use candles instead of "cheap imported" sunshine to light their homes.
In reaction to the political success of the British free traders and the formation of the French Free Trade Association and its summer campaign a group of northern French industrialists formed their own national "Association pour la Défense du Travail National" (Association for the Defense of National Employment). [93] This had begun as a regional lobby group organized by the textile manufacturer Auguste Mimerel in 1842 in the northern manufacturing city of Roubaix. He and the banker and manufacturer Antoine Odier established the national association in Paris in October 1846 which had as its aim to present themselves as defenders of French labor and employment in the factories rather than as lobbyists for the interests of factory owners. Their journal Le Moniteur industriel was often the butt of Bastiat’s satire and ridicule in the pages of Libre-Échange and the articles which later appeared as Economic Sophisms (1846, 1848). The protectionists were also able to launch a publishing program of their own to defend tariff protection with books by Jules Lebastier, Défense du travail national (1846); Thémistocle Lestisboudois, Économie pratique des nations (1847), and Antoine-Marie Roederer, Les douanes et l’industrie en 1848: dangers et nécessités (1847).
The two lobby groups clashed head on when the Chamber agreed to review French tariff policy in early 1847. The free traders had very few deputies or peers in the Chambers and the protectionists had much more experience in working with elected politicians, especially within committees set up to review new legislation. It became clear that as the tariff reform proposal worked its way through committee the free traders had been out-manoeuvred by the protectionists and the measure was defeated. This was a serious blow to the French free trade movement as many of them thought that with the success of the British free traders in the first half of 1846 it would only be a matter of time before the French government would follow suit. Their mistake was that they had not prepared the ground sufficiently as their English counterparts had. The Anti-Corn Law League had been founded in 1838 and it took eight years of popular agitation, public speeches, the collection of thousands of signatures, the publication of popular pamphlets and newspaper articles, wooing members of Parliament, and so on before they had the numbers in the House to repeal the Corn Laws. The French free traders thought they could do the same in 18 months without having the support of a newly enfranchised middle class to back them up. Molinari also thought the conservative protectionists had been smart to also appeal to ordinary workers and to the growing socialist movement by arguing in nationalistic terms that free trade would mean certain unemployment for French workers in the face of British competition.
After their defeat in the Chamber in the summer of 1847 and then with the outbreak of the Revolution in February 1848 the French Free Trade Association decided to wind up its activities and dissolved the organisation in March 1848 so they could focus on the more pressing problem posed by the rise of socialism. They would have to wait until 1860 when Chevalier was able to work within the administration of Napoléon III and get a free trade agreement with Britain imposed from above, since it was clear that a bottom up political movement like the Anti-Corn Law League was impossible to organise in France.
During the 1840s the Paris School had to contend with the rise of an organised socialist movement which challenged their core beliefs about the right to own property, charge interest on loans, charge rent for agricultural land, make a profit from their business, or employ workers at market wage rates. The three leading socialist critics and their main works were Victor Considerant (1808-1893) who wrote Théorie du droit de propriété et du droit au travail (1845); Pierre-Joseph Proudhon (1809-1865) who wrote Qu"est-ce que la propriété? (1840), Système des contradictions économiques (1846), Gratuité du crédit (1850); and Louis Blanc (1811-1882) who wrote L’Organisation du travail (1839).
One can summarize the views of Proudhon and many other socialists who shared his critique of property that the original acquisition of land was unjust because it created a monopoly for the individual owner vis-à-vis the community; that profit is unjust because only things of equal value can be exchanged and this by definition leaves no opportunity for a surplus or profit to one of the parties (similar arguments are made against paying rent for land, or interest on loans); that collective ownership and socially organized economic activity is the only just means for human beings to live and work together; and equality of conditions between people is the only just distribution of property.
Another attack on the right to property in a free market came from socialists like Louis Blanc and Victor Considerant. Their arguments were less well argued and expressed than Proudhon, whom the economists at least recognized as a formidable although ultimately confused intellectual opponent. In their writings they articulated a socialist and cooperative alternative to the system of wage labour in order to appeal to reform-minded workers. Louis Blanc’s most influential work was L’Organisation du travail (The Organisation of Work) (1839) which was first published as an article in the Revue du progrès and which was reprinted many times throughout the 1840s and became a focus for attack by the economists during the Second Republic. Similarly with Considerant’s “Théorie du droit de propriété” (1839).
According to Louis Blanc the free market and the competition it spawned was both anarchic in the way it operated and deadly in its effects on the working class. He thought that free competition was nothing more that “un système d’extermination” (a system of extermination) for the working class, a cause of ruin for the bourgeoisie, and would lead inevitably to war with the best practitioner of competition, which was England. These dire consequences could only be averted if the government became “le régulateur suprême de la production” (the supreme regulator of production) armed with “une grande force” (great coercive powers) to make free competition disappear (faire disparaître la concurrence). His strategy was to use two things to achieve this: “l’organisation” and “l’association”, the organisation of industry and the association of workers, which became code words for socialism throughout the 1840s. His aim was to create state funded “ateliers sociaux” (social workshops) in all the most important branches of industry throughout the economy. Using capital which had been set aside for this purpose (exactly how this would be done was not specified), the state would be the sole director of the social workshops and would regulate their activity. Workers who met the required “garanties de moralité” (moral standards) would be “called” to work there (conscripted perhaps) (tous les ouvriers qui offriraient des garanties de moralité … seraient appelés à travailler dans les ateliers sociaux). [94] As several economists noted in their criticisms of this proposal the model for the state’s control of industry seemed to be based upon the French army or the large central government bureaucracies in Paris.
The ideas of both Blanc and Considerant became very influential after the Revolution broke out in February 1848 as they were part of the provisional government and were elected to the Constituent Assembly where they attempted to put their ideas into practice in the National Workshops and the legislation on the Right to Work. Louis Blanc in particular was influential as the president of the “Commission du gouvernement pour les travailleurs” (Government Commission for the Workers, also known as the Luxembourg Commission) which oversaw the National Workshops program.
Their writings provoked a considerable outpouring of criticism on the part of the economists between 1845 and 1850 who realized the power of their threat to key aspects of the operation of the free market. The first serious efforts by the economists to criticize Blanc’s ideas were by Michel Chevalier in 1844 and Charles Dunoyer in 1845. In a long critique of Blanc in the Journal des Debats in August 1844 Chevalier identified two fundamental flaws in Blanc’s theory which would make his schemes unworkable: the assumption that human societies are principally governed by a sense of duty, not the personal self-interest of the individuals which make up that society; and that the guiding principle of “absolute equality” of wages in the social workshops would result in an increase in the productivity of the workers, not a decrease. Chevalier rejected both ideas as “radicalement erronées” (profoundly wrong) and proceeded to elaborate at some length the incentive problems which would lead the social workshops to ruin. Chevalier returned to Blanc’s ideas in a series of articles he published in the Journal des Débats and the Revue des Deux Mondes during 1848 in which he explored in much more detail the economic objections he had first raised in summary form in 1844. [95]
Another early response to the socialists before the Revolution was written by the doyen of the older generation of liberals, Charles Dunoyer, in a long “post-scriptum” at the end of the first volume of his De la liberté du travail (1845). [96] The three volumes of his magnum opus De la Liberté du travail was devoted to exploring how the principle of the complete liberty to work and produce had evolved historically and what it would mean for human prosperity when a society based upon absolute freedom of working had been brought into existence. Naturally, he found the objections of socialists like Considerant and Blanc to be wrong and misplaced. Dunoyer summed up his objections in five points: that fully free markets did not exist anywhere so it was false to blame economic problems on what did not yet exist; the socialists did not recognize the great advances which had already made in bringing people out of poverty, especially since the Revolution had destroyed so many of the restrictive practices of the Old Regime; that the real causes for poverty had not been properly identified by the socialist critics, which were caused by the persistence of restrictions on trade and production, the burden of taxes, and the never-ending problem of war; that the remedies proposed by the socialists, namely the “the organisation of industry” and “the association of workers” into government controlled “social workshops” would not work; and finally that the real remedy for poverty was more of what the socialists rejected, namely the creation of “un régime de plus en plus réel de liberté et de concurrence” (a regime of more and more real liberty of competition).
In 1846-47 the economists were distracted from continuing their attacks on the socialists by the new free trade movement which had sprung up, so they were caught by surprise when the size of the socialist movement became apparent in late February 1848 when thousands of socialists took to the streets. They were doubly surprised when Louis Blanc was made part of the Provisional Government and was able to push his way forward to seize control of the Luxembourg Palace (the seat of the Chamber of Peers under the old regime) and set up the National Workshops. His plan was to set up a national system of his "social workshops" to provide a working alternative to private firms paying free market wages to workers. Although he lacked funds and eventually faced considerable opposition from within the government it looked to the economists as if their worst nightmares might be about to come true. The economists closed down the French Free Trade Association in order to devote their time and resources to influencing the new government by standing for elections which were called for April and to launch a new kind of campaign against the socialists. This new campaign took the form of writing pamphlets and newspapers designed to appeal to ordinary workers and debating the socialists in the streets.
With the collapse of Louis Philippe's government there was also a collapse in the enforcement of the censorship laws and the restrictions on political associations, thus hundreds of small newspapers appeared on the streets and about 200 "political clubs" of all descriptions were set up to debate the full spectrum of political ideas for the first time in many decades in Paris.
The very next day after the régime fell a group of economists were on the streets of Paris with a hastily put together newspaper called La République française, edited by Frédéric Bastiat, the journalist Hippolyte Castille, and Gustave de Molinari. It appeared in 30 issues between 26 February and 28 March. The format of the magazine was only one or two pages which could be handed out on street corners or pasted to walls so that passers by could read them. [97] In their opening statement of principles they called for many economic reforms which they would repeat many times in the coming issues: the end of state subsidies for religious groups, the end of state control of education, complete freedom of commerce, the end to taxes on food and other essentials, an end to conscription into the army (what Bastiat called the "military tax" on young men), the creation of labour exchanges to help workers find employment, and the "inviolable respect for property." [98] What is remarkable is that the 47 year old Bastiat and the 30 year old Molinari were writing, editing, and handing out these sheets of paper on the streets of Paris in the middle of a revolution trying to persuade workers not to be seduced by socialist arguments for reform. Interestingly, they would do the same thing again in June at the height of the socialist mass protests against the closure of the National Workshops. The second magazine was named Jacques Bonhomme, meaning the French "everyman", to whom they again were trying to appeal. [99] It was founded by Bastiat with the assistance of Gustave de Molinari, Charles Coquelin, Alcide Fonteyraud, and Joseph Garnier. It appeared approximately weekly in four issues between 11 June and 13 July, with a break between 24 June and 9 July because of the rioting during the June Days uprising. Articles appeared on the nature of freedom, laissez-faire economic policies, the fraudulent claims of the government to be able to give whatever the voters wanted, and most interestingly, a draft of what was to become one of Bastiat's best-known essays, “The State.” As the June Days rioting became increasingly violent, Bastiat and his friends were forced to close the magazine after having been caught in the crossfire between the troops and the protesters. [100]
By March over 200 political clubs had been established in Paris. On the socialist side, Louis Blanc was active in his "club des Travailleurs Socialistes" (Socialist Workers Club) and Karl Marx, who was in Paris at the time, was active in the "club des Travailleurs allemands" (German Workers Club) where he was promoting his newly printed "Communist Manifesto." [101] The economists decided to form their own club to debate the socialists face-to-face about their demand for "the right to a job" ("le droit au travail"). They called their club "le club de la Liberté du travail" (the club for the liberty of working) and it was set up by Charles Coquelin. [102] Its first meeting was held on March 31 to discuss the question of “The Organization of Labour” with three socialists defending Louis Blanc’s proposals and attacking free trade, and Coquelin, Fonteyraud, and Garnier defending the free market position of the “Liberty of Working”. Alcide Fonteyraud was one of the Club’s best public speakers who died in the cholera epidemic which swept France in mid 1849. He was famous for his florid and witty style of speaking and his ability to mix references to the classics of French literature with the classics of political economy. Molinari later revealed that the club was forced to close after a few weeks because of violence and intimidation by socialist street thugs (Molinari called them “a gang or a herd of communists”) and expressed regret that the economists had been too easily intimidated and had given up this attempt at spreading free market ideas too easily. [103]
However, taking their battle against socialist ideas onto the streets was only a small part of the economists" activity at this time. A small group of them got elected to the Constituent Assembly in April election where they were able to oppose socialist legislation on the floor of the Chamber. [104] Bastiat was appointed Vic-President of the Finance Committee where he tried to cut taxes (especially on salt and alcohol), cut government expenditure (especially on the military and the National Workshops), and balance the budget, which was very difficult given the collapse in revenues caused by the economic downturn following the Revolution. Bastiat and the other opponents of Blanc's National Workshops were able to persuade the Chamber to close them in May, thus provoking the bloody June Days uprising.
Another tactic of the socialists and their allies in the Chamber was to try to get clauses inserted into the new constitution of the Republic which would provide a government (i.e. tax-payer funded) guarantee of the right to a job for every worker. Pressure was brought to bear by the reprinting of the key works by Considerant and Blanc on "the right to a job" to which the economists Léon Faucher [105] and Michel Chevalier [106] responded by writing a stream of critical articles for journals such as the Journal des Deux mondes and the Journal des Débats which were later collected and published as books. Most notable of these were the Lettres sur l’Organisation du travail written by Chevalier who was no doubt using the free time he had after his dismissal from his teaching post at the Collège de France to good effect. The constitution was debated over the summer of 1848 and the economists, along with other anti-socialist deputies in the Chamber such as Alexis de Tocqueville, were able to prevent these clauses being inserted, which was a considerable victory given the circumstances. [107]
The Guillaumin publishing firm also contributed to the intellectual battle against socialism by cranking up its operations to produce scores of anti-socialist material throughout 1848 and 1849. Before the revolution it had published 30 books in each of the years 1846 and 1847. In 1848 this more than doubled to 67 titles which included books as well as pamphlets and reprints of speeches given by economists in the Chamber, a number the firm would not reach again until 1867. The following year 1849 with 45 titles was the second highest in the firm's history to that time. In 1848 the firm even produced a special library of anti-socialist texts and pamphlets which it advertised in a separate flyer, called "Publications nouvelles sur les questions économiques à l"ordre du jour" (New Publications on the economic questions of the day), which they handed out on the streets of Paris.
In reviewing the events of the previous year two of the younger economists Gustave de Molinari and Alcide Fonteyraud came to some sobering conclusions. Molinari blamed the spread of socialist ideas on the lack of education about political economy among the ruling elite as well as the general public. He dismissed the activities of radicals like Louis Blanc, whose work was impossible to put into practice on a wide scale, as much less of a concern than the beliefs of powerful establishment politicians like Garnier-Pagès, Lamartine, and “conservateurs-bornes” (blinkered conservatives) like Adolphe Thiers, who could use the large government bureaucracies and the Bank of France to implement “socialist” (or rather interventionist) policies throughout the country. Molinari described it as a form of “socialisme infiniment plus dangereux que celui de M. Louis Blanc, car il était plus applicable” (socialism which was infinitely more dangerous than that of Louis Blanc’s because it was easier to put into practice). [108] Many years later, when he wrote Joseph Garnier's obituary, he continued this line of thinking when he distinguished between fighting "le socialisme d'en haut" (socialism from above) which he thought was what the large land owners, industrialists, and their investors were attempting to impose on the ordinary consumer by means of tariffs and state subsidies, and "socialisme d'en bas" (socialism from below) which was what they had faced on the streets of Paris in 1848 by people who wanted the state to guarantee them jobs and other handouts at taxpayer expence. [109]
Two months later Fonteyraud, in a review of Garnier's collection of speeches on the "right to work" legislation the previous summer, pointed out that although the threat of violence in the streets had died down socialist ideas were still pervasive in the minds of the people. He thought the educational strategy the economists needed to adopt was nothing less than “la régénération intellectuelle des classes laborieuses” (the intellectual regeneration of the working classes), something which the socialists had been doing for the past 20 years. [110] Since ideas were such powerful things, if the minds of the people could be swayed toward economic and political liberty as envisaged by the economists, then the economic and political problems which beset France could be ameliorated and events like 1848 could be avoided in the future.
The Guillaumin group of economists acted on the advice of Molinari and Fonteyraud with a two-pronged strategy to spread economic ideas among the political elite ("en haut" - above) as well as ordinary people ("en bas" - below) which they proceeded to roll out over the next four years. It was at this time that planning began for the large compendium of economic knowledge, the Dictionnaire de l"économie politique, which would appear in 1852 under the editorial control of Charles Coquelin. This would be aimed at influencing the elite who ran the government and the bureaucracies, and the intellectuals who wrote for the quality magazines. The second prong was to expand their program of offering popular works on political economy for ordinary readers. This would be based on the successful model created by Bastiat with his two collections of Economic Harmonies. Bastiat was persuaded to write 12 anti-socialist pamphlets over a period of two years which Guillaumin marketed as a collection called "M. Bastiat's Little Pamphlets." Molinari would also contribute to this with a pioneering book published in September 1849, Les Soirées de la rue Saint-Lazare, which consisted of 12 "soirées" which were attended by "a Conservative," "a Socialist", and "an Economist" who debated key economic issues such as private property, intellectual property, agriculture, capital and interest, labour laws, protectionism, money, government subsidies to industry, public goods, and the private provision of police and protection services. [111] Fonteyraud joined with Wolowski to write introductory articles on political economy for a popular encyclopedia called appropriately enough "Education for the People: 100 Articles on the Most Indispensable Knowledge". [112]
A recurring theme during the July Monarchy was the problem of the heavy burden of indirect taxes on the poor, a problem which was only partially solved in the Second Republic. In 1848-49 the tax revenue for the French state came mostly from direct taxes on things like land and other property (30%), fees the bureaucratic state imposed on all kinds of transactions such as registrations and stamp duty (17%), and tariffs and indirect taxes on salt, tobacco, alcohol, sugar (35%). [113] Most of the economists wanted to replace the "protective" tariff (the average rate in 1848 was about 11%) with a low "revenue raising" tariff of 5%, and reduce or abolish all the indirect taxes which weighed most heavily of the poor, and, in the case of Bastiat, replace these with a low, flat rate of income tax imposed on all income earners. Bastiat gave several speeches in the Chamber during the Second Republic urging the abolition of taxes on alcohol, salt, and sending letters through the mail, [114] and tried to persuade his colleagues in the Finance Committee to take his side in the debates. He had limited success given the dire financial position of the new government.
The government's expenditure was also skewed towards paying for the high costs of war (both past and present) and pubic works. Paying off the public debt which had grown as a result of past wars and public works programs took 29% of the total budget in 1848-49; expenditure on the army, navy, and colonies absorbed 30%; and current pubic works 10%, for a total of 69%. Bastiat realised that the only way to cut taxes on the poor was to cut the biggest items of government expenditure, namely to reduce the government's debt and to slash spending on the military. In his essay "The Utopian" (January 1847) he called for disbanding the entire French army of 400,000 men and replacing it with local militias based on the American model (thus saving the budget 400 million francs in one fell swoop); in the pamphlet What is Seen and What is Not Seen (July 1850) he proposed a more modest cut of 100,000 men; [115] and elsewhere he called for the end of conscription for 20 year old men. Conscription was a serious issue as service in the French army was for 7 years unless the conscript could pay for a replacement to take his place (the going rate was between fr. 1,800-2,400). He called the seven years taken from a young man's earning years the equivalent of a "military tax" imposed on young working class men. [116]
When the international Friends of Peace movement held their annual meeting in Paris in August 1849 a strong contingent from the Political Economy Society was present. Joseph Garnier kept the minutes and was the editor of the Conference Proceedings, Bastiat gave one of the keynote speeches (following Richard Cobden), and Molinari wrote an article for the JDE summarising its conclusions and resolutions. [117] The Conference President was the novelist Victor Hugo who stressed the high cost of wars throughout the 19th century and the burden this placed on ordinary working people, as well as the opportunity costs of military spending which might have been used instead to build more factories or housing for the poor. Bastiat picked up this theme in his speech and pointed out that the high cost of military spending meant that indirect taxes had to be kept high to pay for it, which meant that this placed a heavy and unequal burden on the poor, and this in turn was a legitimate grievance of the poor who sought redress in revolutionary activity such as in February 1848. In order to avoid another revolution, he concluded, taxes had to be abolished or drastically cut, and to do this military expenditure also had to be cut by an equal or greater amount. [118]
An example of misguided government expenditure on military matters was the massive public works undertaken to build "the fortifications of Paris" between 1841 and 1844. In 1840 the President of the Council of Ministers, Adolphe Thiers was concerned that Britain’s opposition to French policy to support the Pascha of Egypt might lead to another war. To deter this possibility, he planned to build a massive military wall 33 km (21 miles) in circumference around the city of Paris with 16 star-shaped forts laid out in an outer perimeter beyond the wall. All people and goods entering or leaving the city had to pass through one of the 17 large entry gates built into the wall. This project was budgeted to cost fr. 150 million and was completed in 1844. The total expenditure would have been much higher if the state had not used the labour of thousands of army conscripts to dig the ditches and build the wall. “Thiers’ Wall,” as it was known, was strongly opposed by liberals such as the astronomer and mathematician François Arago [119] and the economist Michel Chevalier, [120] who objected to its construction because it was so expensive, that military technology would soon make it obsolete, and that the wall would one day be used to “imprison” the citizens of Paris if they ever rose up in rebellion to demand much needed political and economic reforms (which they did of course in February 1848, and were duly put down by troops stationed in the forts around Paris). In other words, the wall resulted in the “embastillisation” of Paris (the Bastillisation of Paris). [121]
In very general terms we can see a significant change taking place in the period under discussion about the nature and purpose of economic activity. There was a gradually expanding notion of what constituted productive activity, with the Physiocrats seeing it almost exclusively in agriculture, then the production of "wealth" in the form of material goods (Smith) and the exchange of that wealth (Whately). A significant shift occurred with J.-B. Say who introduced the idea of the "production" of "non-material goods" (services) being as important as the "stuff" of material goods in economic activity. A further expansion took place in the writing of Dunoyer who argued that productive activity of any kind which produced any thing which people wanted to exchange with others was "productive" and constituted a new form of society known as an "industrial" or "industrious" society, where "industry" meant human activity in the broadest possible sense.
The culmination of this line of thinking was reached in the work of Bastiat who attempted to make his economic thinking as abstract as possible, where the physicality or materiality of the goods or services exchange were irrelevant. Hence his interest in reducing political economy to the study of any "economising activity" an individual might make with the scarce resources they had at their disposal. His use of thought experiments involving the choices faced by Robinson Crusoe on the Island of Despair have many similarities with late 20th century Austrian economics and suggest that Bastiat should be regarded as a proto-Austrian in many respects. [122] A further abstraction was to see all economic activity as the "mutual exchange of services", even if physical, material goods were being exchanged, or the services of an opera singer or judge, or even in a land owner renting his land to a farmer.
Also in this period we can see a shift taking place in thinking about the purpose of economic activity. Increasingly, it was no longer the mercantilist idea of maximising the production of things for the benefit of the nation state or various "national industries" by selling them abroad and increasing the nation's "balance of trade." The purpose of economic activity was seen as being for the benefit of consumers not the producers or the nation state. Again, Bastiat took a leading role in pushing political economy in this "consumer-centric" direction.
One of the threads running through the three generations of the Paris School under discussion is the strong, radical liberal, and anti-statist thread which links J.B. Say in the beginning, runs through Charles Comte and Charles Dunoyer in the middle, and ends with Charles Coquelin, Gustave de Molinari, and Frédéric Bastiat in the late 1840s. The issues they were concerned with were free banking, the private provision of public goods, and the inherent harmony or disharmony of the free market, respectively.
Coquelin was a pioneer theorist of free banking, that is the idea that the issuing of money was not a public good which only a state bank or a state-authorized private monopoly should provide. He argued that private banks should be allowed to compete with each other to supply the "service" of having money to use when making transactions. Napoléon Bonaparte had created the Bank of France in 1800 which was a private bank in which he personally owned shares. It was given a monopoly in 1803, something which Say had strenuously opposed at the time. Payment in specie (i.e. gold) upon demand was suspended twice in the 19th century, both times during revolutions, in 1848-1850 and 1870-1875. In the early months of 1848 the banks of the different Departments were merged into the Bank of France in an attempt to solve the fiscal crisis brought on by the Revolution. There was also strong pressure coming from socialists like Proudhon for the state to set up a "Peoples Bank" which would issue free credit to workers so they could more easily set up new businesses. [123] Proudhon and Bastiat had a long debate on this question at the end of 1849 which appeared in book form as Gratuité du crédit (1850) in which Bastiat came out in favour of free banking as articulated by Coquelin.
Coquelin wrote articles on the banking system of the United States and England during the 1830s and admired their relative freedom of operation. In 1840 when the Chamber was discussing renewing the monopoly of the Back of France for another 27 years he published his first book, Des banques au France (1840), in which he argued for the right of private banks to compete in the issuing of currency. He wrote many more articles on banking, currency, and commercial crises throughout the 1840s, culminating in his main work Du Crédit et des Banques (1848) which appeared during the banking crises of the Revolution, and several key articles on Banks, Bank Notes, the Assignats currency of the Revolution, Commercial Crises, and Credit for the DEP. [124] The theory of free banking would be further developed by Jean-Gustave Courcelle-Seneuil (1813-1892) in the 1850s and 1860s. [125]
The Paris School economists were divided over the proper size and functions of the state, ranging from the "ultra-minimalists" like Bastiat (police, local militias for defence, and very few public works), to the middle ground of the majority who were in favour of the standard "Smithian" role of the state (police, defence, and a handful of public goods like roads and money and possibly basic education), to the more statist among them like Louis Wolowski who wanted the government to run banks and supply cheap credit for farmers. The outliers were Molinari (and sometimes Say in his unpublished lectures and the younger Dunoyer) who thought that even police and defence might be better provided by private competing companies or voluntarily by local communities. He went so far as to advocate the radical break up of the centralised bureaucratic state into much smaller jurisdictions, or what he called “the municipalisation of the world.” [126]
The seeds of doubt about the productivity of state activity had been sown by Tracy and Say who had argued that most if not all consumption by the state was "unproductive", as for example Tracy in the conclusion in A Commentary and Review of Montesquieu (1817) that all state expenditure was “sterile and unproductive.” [127] Say had argued in his lectures at the Athénée in the late 1810s that since protection was a "non-material" good like many others that “entrepreneurs” would have an interest in providing security services. [128] The next step came to Molinari in 1846 when he was thinking about the need for electoral reform and began using the metaphor of an insurance company, where he likened the state, perhaps for the first time, to “une grande compagnie d'assurances mutuelles” (a large mutual insurance company), taxes to “charges de l’association” (membership dues), and the taxpayers to “un actionnaire de la société” (a shareholder in the company). [129] This was also a metaphor the conservative politician Adolphe Thiers also used two years later in his book De la propriété (1848) but not with the same intent as Molinari. [130]
Molinari abandoned the metaphor in an article on "The Production of Security (JDE, February 1849) in which he seriously proposed that all police and national defence services could and should be provided competitively on the free market. He argued that in a free market for security services entrepreneurs or “les producteurs de sécurité” (producers of security) would set up private companies to sell security to “les consommateurs de sécurité” (consumers of security) who would pay a fee for the service. [131] He would take this up again in chapter 11 of his book Les Soirées where he took the next step of imagining exactly what kind of companies would provide security for consumers, namely “les compagnies d’assurances sur la propriété” (property insurance companies) which would behave like other insurance companies by charging premiums to protect their customers lives and property from attack. He calls this system "la liberté de gouvernement" (the freedom to choose one's government) which would function much like the system of "la liberté des échanges" (free trade) did for all other goods and services. [132] In the rest of the book he also argued, chapter by chapter, how all government provided public goods, such as roads, water supplies, mail delivery, and so on, could be replaced by private companies offering their services in a free market. The members of the Political Economy Society discussed his book at the October 1849 and rejected his ideas unanimously, with Dunoyer suggesting that Molinari had been carried away by "delusions of logic." [133]
In spite of his colleagues’ criticism and his intellectual isolation on this topic, Molinari continued to work on these ideas for at least the next 30 years. He developed them much more fully in two later works, the treatise based upon his lectures at the Athénée royal in Paris, the Cours d’économie politique, which he began in late 1847 and completed after he had moved to Brussels in 1852 and was teaching again, this time at the Musée royale de l"industrie belge; and the second volume of his work on the historical sociology and economics of the state which appeared in 1884, L’Évolution politique et la Révolution after Molinari had returned to Paris and had taken up the post of editor of the Journal des Économistes in 1881. [134]
The most original and innovative theorist at the end of the 1840s was Bastiat. He had started his career as an economic journalist and free trade advocate late in life (at the age of 44) before realising that he had some significant contributions to make to economic theory as well. Unfortunately, because of his failing health (he died on December 24, 1850 from cancer of the throat) and the many distractions of being a politician during the revolution he was unable to complete much more than the first volume of a planned trilogy of works on Social Harmonies, Economic Harmonies, and a History of Plunder (or what might also be called his Economic and Social Disharmonies). Among his many interesting ideas were his opposition to Malthusian pessimism, a new theory of rent, the idea of the harmony of the market vs. political disturbing factors which upset that harmony, the idea of ceteris paribus ("all things being equal"), [135] the idea of opportunity cost, and an early version of a subjective theory of value.
The reasons for his opposition to Malthus's pessimism have been discussed briefly above. The reaction of the other economists to his 1846 article "On Population" was very hostile, as Joseph Garnier and Molinari were staunch Malthusians, which caused Bastiat to rewrite the article for inclusion in the second volume of the Economic Harmonies. He only had one supporter among the economists for his more optimist view about population growth, Roger de Fontenay, who added a justificatory appendix to Bastiat's chapter XVI in the second posthumous edition (1851) in a largely unsuccessful attempt to defend Bastiat's views. [136] In addition to thinking that the Malthusians had got the arithmetic wrong in asserting that populations inevitably increased geometrically in size, he also had original views about the benefits to society of people living in larger urban centres, such as the reduction in transaction costs for engaging in trade with others, the greater possibilities for the division of labour and thus greater productivity, and the idea that humans themselves were a form of capital who added value rather than subtracted value from society.
A second area where Bastiat stood alone from his colleagues was the question of land rent. The Ricardian orthodox view had come under attack from socialists during the 1840s who quite rightly pointed out that according to Ricardo the "free gift of the soil" was a form of "unearned income" for the land owner, since he had not expended labour in producing it. Most of the economists shrugged this off as an unfortunate price society had to pay in order to get the great benefits to be had from the private ownership of land. Bastiat thought that the socialists were right to expose this serious flaw in orthodox economic theory, which had opened a very wide door for further criticism not just of rent but also of profit and interest, which in his view could only be fixed by rejecting Ricardian notions about rent and forging a completely new theory.
Bastiat did this by arguing that land was not unique in having a "natural component" which made it useful to and valuable for humans. The same could be said for many other natural resources like coal (humans did not create but found coal deposits) and natural forces like the compressibility of steam (which could be harnessed for steam engines). The value or "service" humans provided was in finding the resource, preparing it for use, maintaining it so it could be used by others, taking the risk of spending resources to get it to market, and supplying it in a form that others wanted. Thus Bastiat concluded that land rent was just another "service" one person rendered to another when they voluntarily entered into transactions with each other. [137] Under competitive pressures Bastiat believed that the "value" (or what we would call "the price") of these natural resources would be driven down to the point were they were practically "gratuitous" or free of charge and thus become become part of what was "common to all." [138]
Like his ideas on Malthus, Bastiat's theory of rent was not well received by his colleagues. [139]
Bastiat today is best known for his theory of the natural harmony of the free market. What is not as well known is the counterpoint to this argument, that "disharmonies" inevitably appear when "disturbing factors", such as acts of coercion and plunder, intervene to disrupt this underlying economic harmony. [140] Bastiat believed that it was part of "le plan providentiel" (the providential plan) that human beings were endowed with certain patterns of behaviour or internal drives (les mobiles) such as the pursuit of self-interest, the avoidance of pain or hardship and the seeking of pleasure or well-being, free will, the ability to plan for the future, and to choose from among alternatives that are presented to them. Or in other words, that mankind had a certain "nature." These were all part of the natural laws which governed human behaviour and made economies operate in the way that they did. His conclusion was that if human beings were allowed to go about their lives freely and in the absence of government or other forms of coercion the result would be a "harmonious society."
This would arise as people came to learn that by cooperating with each other, by participating in the division of labour, by exchanging with each other in a non-coercive manner the things they made or the services they could offer, everybody could be made better off than if they acted alone. Individual self-interest and the forces of competition were vital components in this process of "harmonisation" as self-interest is what drives individuals to make efforts to produce things to sell to others, and competition between producers is what drives them to better satisfy the needs of their customers.
Bastiat was not alone in coming to these conclusions as the American economist Henry Carey published a book the following year on The Harmony of Interests agricultural, manufacturing, and commercial (1851). [141]
Since it was obvious that "harmony" did not reign in France, especially in the year of revolution of 1848, Bastiat also had to explain why this was the case. In his view, harmony would be the result of the strict respect for individual liberty and the right to property. "Disharmony" occurred when private property and liberty were violated by "oppression" and "plunder." These were the root causes of the "disturbing factors" such as war, the imposition of slavery, exorbitant taxation, trade restrictions, and the exercise of what he called "legal plunder" by those who sought special privileges from the state. After finishing his treatise on Econmic Harmonies Bastiat planned to write a History of Plunder in which he would trace the long history of plunder through various stages, as Comte and Dunoyer had done in the 1820s, beginning with primitive forms of plunder, war, slavery, theocracy, the régime of monopoly (mercantilism), governmental exploitation (19th century France), and what he called "false fraternity" or communism which Louis Blanc had tried to implement in early 1848. [142]
The modern political economist Anthony de Jasay thinks that Bastiat's greatest contribution to economic theory is his notion of opportunity cost, [143] or what he called "the seen" and "the unseen." By "unseen" Bastiat meant the things that one has to give up or forego in order to receive a given benefit. He devoted the last major work he wrote before he died to exploring this concept with 12 specific examples in What Is Seen and What Is Not Seen (July 1850), such as broken windows, closing a military base, cutting state subsidies to theatres, and so on. [144] The classic statement of this was the story about the shop owner Jacque Bonhomme whose son breaks the shop window. Jacques has to pay a glazier to replace it which prompts some of his friends to remind him that it is not a complete loss as it gives additional work to the glazier. Bastiat then explains the opportunity cost involved, namely the fact that Jacques has a broken asset which needs to be replaced at a certain cost, and thus no longer has that money to buy a chicken for his next meal, thus affecting the livelihood of the butcher.
Late 20th century Austrian economists have been drawn to Bastiat because he developed a number of ideas which would be explored in more detail by theorists like Carl Menger in the 1870s, such as subjective value theory, and Ludwig von Mises in the 1940s, such as the logic of human action. This is not to argue that Bastiat was an Austrian, only that he had a number of Austrian-like insights which might make him a kind of "proto-Austrian." A good example of this is his rejection of the idea that "value" was determined by an "objective" quantity of labour or some measurable amount of some "utility". Although not yet a complete subjectivist (he continued to reject the ideas of Condillac and Henri Storch who argued that both parties made a "profit" in an exchange; [145] and still believed that things of "equivalent value" were exchanged) he did recognise that each person "evaluated" [146] the goods or services they wanted to exchange in a unique way, depending upon their particular place, personal circumstances, and needs.
Scattered throughout Bastiat's writings are many intriguing statements which prefigure some key ideas of the Austrian School of economic thought which emerged during the 1870s as represented by Carl Menger and Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk, and in the twentieth century by Ludwig von Mises, Friedrich Hayek, and Murray Rothbard. We say “prefigure” because he did not present a coherent Austrian theory of subjective value theory, time preference, or the business cycle, but he did have an understanding of other things like the fact that only individuals choose, that exchange is fundamental to the economic order, that utility is based upon subjective evaluations, that the price system is important in giving direction to what is produced, that money is not neutral, and that social institutions are often the result of human action and not “artificially” designed.
For example, Bastiat refers several times to humans as “un être actif” (an acting or active being), “un agent” (an agent, or actor), “un agent intelligent” (an intelligent or thinking actor), and to their behaviour in the economic world as “l’action humaine” (human action) or “l’action de l’homme” (the action of human beings, or human action), and to the guiding principle behind it all as “le principe actif" or “le principe d’activité” (the principle of action). [147] These ideas were beginning to come together in the Economic Harmonies which he began writing in earnest in 1848 with the essays “Natural and Artificial Organization" (Jan. 1848) and the opening chapters "Economic Harmonies I, II, III” (Sept. 1848, and number IV in December 1848. He also used the idea of human action in his thought experiments involving Robinson Crusoe to explain the nature of human action in the abstract.
A final theme which runs through the Paris School from beginning to end is a theory of class based upon who has access to the power of the state to gain privileges at the expense of others. One might normally associate theories of class and exploitation with Marxist thinkers but, as Marx himself openly acknowledged, [148] he got his ideas about class from the French political economists and liberal historians like Augustin Thierry. The issue turned on the question of what activities were "productive" and what ones were "non-productive" or even outright "parasitical" which, as we have seen, occupied Say, Comte, and Dunoyer in the earl Restoration period. In the case of Dunoyer, society was deeply divided into two groups, the productive "industrial class" who created the goods and services which were bought and sold in the market place, and an exploiting class of "conquerors" and "plunderers" who used their access to state power to get privileges for themselves at the expense of ordinary peasants, workers, and tax payers. Society was evolving from earlier stages where societies had been divided between slave-owners and slaves, then aristocratic land owners and their serfs, then monarchical or imperial bureaucratic states and their regulated and taxed subjects. Dunoyer believed that modern European societies were on the verge of entering a new "industrial stage" where class rule would come to an end and the hard working "industrial class" could enjoy the fruits of their labour unmolested.
Bastiat picked up Comte and Dunoyer's ideas 30 years later and developed his own theory of plunder which distinguished "extra-legal plunder", that is plunder undertaken outside the law and without its sanction by common thieves and highway robbers, from "legal plunder" which was organised plunder carried out by the state (through taxes, conscription, and regulation of individual activity) or with its sanction (granting tariffs, subsides, and monopolies to a privileged few). [149] He further categorised legal plunder into two types: "partial plunder" where a small elite of landowners or factory owners received tariff protection, subsidies, or monopolies) to plunder the majority of consumers and tax-payers; and "universal (or reciprocal) plunder" which he saw emerging during the Second Republic. Bastiat thought that there was some perverse logic to "partial plunder" which guaranteed benefits for a small ruling elite and their supporters, but it was madness, he thought, to attempt "plunder" on a universal scale where everybody thought they could benefit from a government provided job, government funded education, government supplied old age pensions, government supplied "free credit" or low interest loans, and so on. He described the imaginary state where this would happen as "the great fiction by which everyone endeavours to live at the expence of everyone else." [150]
These ideas were taken up by Ambroise Clément (1805-86) who published a more detailed taxonomy of "legal plunder" in an essay which was published just after the bloody uprising of the June Days in Paris, "De la spoliation légale" (JDE, July 1848), where he discusses different kinds of legal theft or plunder, such as aristocratic theft, monarchical theft, regulatory theft, industrial theft, "supposedly philanthropic" theft, and administrative theft.
A final summing up of this approach was provided by Molinari from his self-imposed exile in Brussels at the end of 1852, on the eve of Louis Napoléon's self-proclamation as Emperor Napoléon III who provided the most sophisticated liberal theory of class analysis to date in Les Révolutions et le despotisme envisagés au point de vue des intérêts matériel (1852) where he provides a cost-benefit analysis of the wars and revolutions which have swept over France over the previous 60 years, and who might have benefited from that. [151] His conclusion was that the class of "des mangeurs de taxes" (the tax eating class) has won out over "des payeurs de taxes" (the tax tax-paying class) and will continue to do so until they can be stopped.
Towards the end of our period there was another depletion in the ranks of the Paris School, but because the school was much bigger than it had been in the early 1830s these losses were not as costly to the movement as a whole. Eugène Daire (1798-1847), the editor of the massive historical Collection des Principaux Économistes died at the age of 49 just before the project reached completion; Alcide Fonteyraud (1822-1849), the brilliant young scholar of Ricardo and outstanding public debater, died in the cholera epidemic that swept through Paris in 1849 killing twenty thousand people; Frédéric Bastiat (1801-1850), possibly the most original thinker in the School and one of the greatest economic journalists who has ever lived, died of throat cancer as he struggled to finish his magnum opus; and Charles Coquelin (1802-1852), the theorist of free banking and the editor of the School's extraordinary DEP, dropped dead from a heart attack while working on volume two. Another important loss to the Paris group was Gustave de Molinari, who went into voluntary exile in Brussels in 1852 rather than live in France under Emperor Napoléon III. He would eventually return to Paris in 1868 when Napoléon III began to liberalise his régime to take up the editorship of the prestigious Journal des Débats. On the death of Joseph Garnier in 1881 Molinari would take over editing the Journal des Économistes and would thus be again at the centre of the Paris School's activities.
The centre of the Guillaumin network, Guillaumin himself, died in 1864. The publishing firm he had founded would continue to support the liberal political economists under the direction of his oldest daughter Félicité, and after her death it was handed over to his youngest daughter Pauline, who managed the firm until it was taken over by Félix Alcan in 1906, after 70 years in business and having published 2,356 book on economics. From its founding in 1837 until the end of our period in 1852 Guillaumin published 360 books on economics and 140 sizable issues of the JDE, a quite remarkable achievement.
C’est que les économistes ne se contentent pas de phrases creuses et de formules vides de sens; c’est qu’ils vont an fond des choses; c’est qu’ils se donnent la peine de dresser le compte des révolutions, expédient dont ne s’avisent guère les esprits enthousiastes qui poussent à la roue des révolutions et qu’elles ne manquent jamais d’écraser dans leurs reculs. Or, comme les révolutions ne résistent pas à l’épreuve de la tenue des livres en partie double; comme les révolutions sont de grandes mangeuses, des dissipatrices effrénées qui engloutissent en quelques jours les épargnes accumulées pendant des siècles; comme elles n’ont le plus souvent à donner au peuple, en échange de son épargne et de la vie de ses enfants, que des paroles échauffantes et des utopies malsaines, les économistes, qui sont les teneurs de livres de la politique, ont crié haro sur les révolutions et déclaré une guerre mortelle aux révolutionnaires. |
It’s because the economists do not content themselves with empty phrases and slogans devoid of any sense. It’s because they want to get to the bottom of things. It’s because they take it upon themselves the trouble of drawing up a balance sheet of the revolutions, which is an exercise which hardly enters the minds of the enthusiasts who carry the torch for revolution and which they never fail to leave out of their recollections. Now, since revolutions do not pass the test of double entry book keeping, since revolutions are the great devourers and the frenzied spendthrifts who wolf down in a few days the accumulated savings of centuries, since they most often have to give to the people, in exchange for their savings and the lives of their children, only some rousing words and some unwholesome utopias, the economists, who are the book keepers of (public) policy, have raised a hue and cry against revolutions and have declared a war to the death against revolutionaries. |
The English political philosopher Larry Siedentop recognised in an essay on "The Two Liberal Traditions" (1979) that French liberalism constituted a distinct second tradition of liberal thought which was very different to its better known English counterpart. [153] What made it so was its "social dimension", to which I would add its "economic dimension." The experience of going through three revolutions (1789, 1830, 1848), one military dictatorship, observing the class conflicts which emerged during those revolutions, the return of a conservative and authoritarian monarchy, the slowness of industrialisation compared with Britain, and the rise of an organised socialist movement meant that the French liberals were naturally concerned with issues such as the nature of political and economic power, the nature of class structure and exploitation, and the historical origins of revolution. These interests lead them to develop systematic theories of social change where a central rôle was given to understanding the changing modes of production which influenced social relations and ideas, and where the concept of class and exploitation was central to their historical analysis. Siedentop concludes that these ideas "were introduced by French liberal thinkers, and only later adapted by socialist writers" like Karl Marx. [154]
The new tradition of classical liberalism which was forged by the first generation of the Paris School built upon the theory of free trade articulated by Adam Smith and the Physiocrats by adding the following key ideas in a unique and original way: the political liberalism of Benjamin Constant; a natural rights rights defence of property and opposition to state coercion; the "industrialist" theory of class of Charles Comte, Charles Dunoyer, and Augustin Thierry; the theory of exchange, markets, and entrepreneurs of Destutt de Tracy, Jean-Baptiste Say, and Gustave de Molinari (who summed up their approach as "markets in everything, and entrepreneurs in every market"); a theory of the state which saw it as the result of conquest, usurpation, and plunder of Constant, Thierry, Bastiat, and Ambroise Clément; the private provision of many (perhaps all) public goods theory of Charles Coquelin and Molinari; and the beginnings of a subjective value theory by Condillac, Henri Storch, and Bastiat.
The Paris School eventually went into decline in the late 19th century as they were pushed aside by the rise of other schools of thought such as Charles Gide's "school of solidarity" which became very influential in the restructured universities after the reforms of 1878, the appearance of neo-classicism with the work of Alfred Marshall, [155] the rise of socialism, and their apparent inability to attract new blood as classical liberalism went out of fashion throughout Europe. By the end of the First World War it had practically disappeared and was well on the way to being forgotten.
The rediscovery of the Paris School began with the rediscovery of the works of Bastiat in California in 1944 by the conservative newspaper publisher R.C. Hoiles who reprinted Bastiat's Economic Sophisms and Economic Harmonies as part of his campaign against Roosevelt's New Deal. [156] This lead to the rediscovery of Comte, Dunoyer, and Molinari by a group of economists and historians who were part of Ludwig von Mises" seminar at New York University in the 1950s. These included the economist Murray Rothbard and the historians Leonard Liggio and Ralph Raico who called their group the "Bastiat Circle" in homage to one of the leading figures of the Paris School. [157] Their early work has stimulated an interest in the School which continues today with work by the economists Joseph Salerno and Jörg Guido Hülsmann, [158] the sociologist Robert Leroux, [159] the present author, [160] and the non-profit educational foundation Liberty Fund which has undertaken a large translation project to bring many works by leading members of the Paris School to a broader English-speaking audience (Destutt de Tracy, Constant, Bastiat, and Molinari). [161]
The School's re-discovery by French scholars did not take place until the 1990s with work by Florin Aftalion, Henri Lepage, Pierre Garello, Philippe Nataf, [162] Michel Leter; [163] Yves Breton, Michel Lutfalla, André Tiran, and Gilbert Faccarello; [164] and the journalist Gérard Minart, [165] and other members of the Institut Charles-Coquelin such as the businessman Jacques de Guenin. [166] The pinnacle of these efforts is the publication of a definitive, scholarly edition of the Collected Works of J.B. Say under André Tiran's direction which began in 2006. [167]
What is still lacking is a new, scholarly edition of the Dictionnaire de l"économie politique to give the achievements of the Paris School the justice it deserves.
Malheureusement, on n’écoute guère les économistes. |
Unfortunately, hardly anyone listens to the economists. |
[1] Say "Cours à l"Athénée" (1819), 4th Séance, "Suite des consommations publiques," Oeuvres, vol. IV, p. 117
[2] The term "Paris School" was coined by Michel Leter in his pioneering essay “Éléments pour une étude de l’École de Paris (1803-1852)" (2006). He included a total of 62 individual authors, politicians, and activists in his lists. See the Appendix "The Three Generations of the Paris School" below for details. See also the survey in Alain Béraud and Philippe Steiner, “France, economics in (before 1870)” and “France, economics in (after 1870)” in The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics (2008).
[3] Two recent surveys of nineteenth century French liberal thought have noted the important contributions made by the Paris School: Robert Leroux and David Hart eds. French Liberalism in the 19th Century: An Anthology (2012) and L"âge d`or du libéralisme français. Anthologie. XIXe siècle (2014).
[4] Rothbard, Classical Economics (2006), Chapter 1 "J.B. Say: the French tradition in Smithian clothing," pp. 1-45, and "Bastiat and the French laissez-faire tradition," pp. 444 ff.
[5] "Boisguillebert est le premier anneau de cette chaine savante qui est formée successivement, jusqu"à nos jours, par les noms illustres de Quesnay, de Smith, de J.-B. Say, de Malthus, de Ricardo et de Rossi." Daire, "Notice historique sur la vie et les travaux de Boisguillebert", in CPE T. I. Économistes financiers du XVIIIe siècle (1843), p. 151.
[6] Fontenay, Du Revenu foncière (1854), Préface," pp. i-iii.
[7] Quatre écoles d'économie sociale (1890), p. 229. The speeches are discussed in David M. Hart, "For Whom the Bell Tolls: The School of Liberty and the Rise of Interventionism in French Political Economy in the Late 19thC" (2017).
[8] Pierre de Boisguilbert, Le Détail de la France sous le régime présent (1697), Factotum de la France (1707), Traité de la nature, culture, commerce et intérêt des grains (1707), Cause de la rareté de l"argent (1707), and Dissertation sur la nature des richesses, de l"argent et les tributs (no date).
[9] Richard Cantillon, Essai sur la nature du commerce en général (1755).
[10] Quesnay wrote the articles on “Fermiers” and “Grains” for Diderot’s Encyclopédie (1756), Le Tableau économique (1762), and Physiocratie, ou constitution naturelle de gouvernement le plus avantageux au genre humain (1768).
[11] Condillac, Le Commerce et le gouvernement considérés relativement l"un a l"autre (1798).
[12] Turgot, Eloge de Gournay (1759), Réflexions sur la formation et la distribution des richesses (1766), and Lettres sur la liberté du commerce des grains (1770).
[13] Their key works were translated and published in volumes V and VI (Smith), volumes VII and VIII (Malthus), volume XIII (Ricardo), and volume XV (Bentham).
[14] Maurice Block, Les progrès de la science économique depuis Adam Smith (1890).
[15] We have modified Leter's division of the generations slightly. He calls "precursors" what I prefer to call the first generation. I believe the Physiocrats are the true "precursors" of the Paris School. See the "Appendix: The Three Generations of the Paris School" for details.
[16] Dunoyer, L"Industrie et la Morale (1825), FN on p. 366-67.
[17] Leter lists a total of 13 people in this generation of which I have selected five of the most important to discuss here. See the "Appendix: The Three Generations of the Paris School" for details.
[18] Destutt de Tracy, Eléments d'idéologie (1803-1815, 1817–1818). Vol. 4 Traité d'économie politique was published as a separate book in 1823. See also Tracy, Commentaire sur l"esprit des lois de Montesquieu (1819).
[19] Benjamin Constant, Les Principes de Politique (1806, 1815), De l’esprit de conquête et de l’usurpation (1814), "De la liberté de l"industrie" (1818), "De la liberté des anciens comparée à celles des modernes" (1819), Commentaire sur l’ouvrage de Filangieri (1822-24), "De M. Dunoyer et de quelques-un de ses ouvrages" (1829).
[20] Jean-Baptiste Say, Traité d’économie politique (1803, 1814, 1817, 1819, 1826), Politique pratique (c. 1815), Leçons d’économie politique (Athénée 1819, Conservatoire 1820-29), and Cours complet d'économie politique pratique (1828-29).
[21] Charles Comte, "De l"organisation sociale considérée dans ses rapports avec les moyens de subsistance des peuples" (1817), "De la multiplication des pauvres, des gens à places, et des gens à pensions" (1818), Traité de législation (1827) and Traité de la propriété (1834).
[22] Charles Dunoyer, "Politique tirée des doctrines économiques" (1818), "De l"influence qu"exercent sur le gouvernement les salaires attachés à l"exercise des fonctions publiques" (1819), L"Industrie et la morale considérées dans leurs rapports avec la liberté (1825), "Fragments de critiques économiques" (1827), and "Esquisse historique des doctrines auxquelles on a donné le nom industrialisme" (1827).
[23] Tracy, Treatise on Political Economy, Chap. V "Of the Change of Place, or of Commercial Industry," pp. 133 ff.
[24] Tracy, Treatise on Political Economy, p. 95.
[25] In the first paragraph on page one of volume 1 of Cours complet Say states that the subject under study was "une science, à laquelle on a donné le nom d'économie politique, et qu"on aurait peut-être mieux fait de nommer économie sociale." See Cours complet d'économie politique pratique (Guillaumin ed. 1840), vol. 1, p. 1 with the explanatory footnote. See also vol. 2, pp. 556-57. Note also that the "second title" (as it were) on the title page of the 1828 edition was "l"Économie des sociétés" (the Economy of Societies).
[26] The first edition of the Traite appeared in 1803, and a further 4 editions appeared in his lifetime: 2nd revised edition 1814, 3rd ed. 1817, 4th revised edition 1819, 5th edition 1826. A 6th revised edition was edited by his son Horace Say in 1841 as part of the massive Collection des principaux économistes edited by Eugène Daire. A translation of the 4th edition by Princep appeared in 1821 in London and in Boston, with the latter having additional material and notes by Clement Biddle. It is most unfortunate that this is still the only translation in English of this key work in which the key concept of "entrepreneur" is unfortunately translated as "adventurer". A variorum French edition comparing all the changes Say made did not appear until 2006 edited by Claude Mouchot for Economica.
[27] It is striking how much effort Say put into making economic ideas more approachable to the average reader. His first effort was the inclusion at the end of the 2nd revised edition of the Traité (1814) of an "Epitome of the Fundamental Principles of Political Economy"; a rather clumsy "Catechism of Political Economy" (1815); and then a Little Book of Economic Insights (1817). On Say's attempts at popularising economic ideas see David M. Hart, "Broken Windows and House-Owning Dogs: The French Connection and the Popularization of Economics from Bastiat to Jasay" (2015) and the earlier unpublished version of this paper which covers Say as well: “Negative Railways, Turtle Soup, talking Pencils, and House owning Dogs: "The French Connection” and the Popularization of Economics from Say to Jasay," (September, 2014).
[28] On the impact Say had, see Weinburg, Mark, "The Social Analysis of Three Early 19th Century French Liberals: Say, Comte, and Dunoyer" (1978).
[29] Éphraïm Harpaz, Le Censeur. Le Censeur européen. Histoire d'un Journal libéral et industrialiste (2000).
[30] On the theory of industrialism, see David M. Hart, Class Analysis, Slavery and the Industrialist Theory of History in French Liberal Thought, 1814-1830: The Radical Liberalism of Charles Comte and Charles Dunoyer (1994); Robert Leroux, The Foundations of Industrialism: Charles Comte, Charles Dunoyer and Liberal Thought in France (2016).
[31] Stendhal was interested in the industrialist theory of history and used some its ideas about the different ways in which ambitious young men can enrich themselves in his novels. See, Stendhal, D"un nouveau complot contre les industriels (1972); Fernand Rudé, Stendhal et la pensée sociale de son temps (1983). And the novels Le Rouge et le Noir (1830) and Lucien Leuwen (1834).
[32] Benjamin Constant, De l"esprit de conquête et de l"usurpation (1814); "De la liberté des anciens comparée à celles des modernes" (1819), Principles of Politics Applicable to a all Governments (1815) Book XI "On Taxation" and Book XII "On Government Jurisdiction over Economic Activity and Population", "De la Liberté d'industrie" (1818), Commentaire sur l’ouvrage de Filangieri (1822-24). 2 vols. Constant's most direct engagement with the "industrialist" liberal school came with his essay "De M. Dunoyer et de quelques-un de ses ouvrages" (1829).
[33] Saint-Chamans was a deputy (1824-27) and a Councillor of State. He advocated protectionism and a mercantilist theory of the balance of trade. He is author of Du système d'impôt fondé sur les principes de l"économie politique (1820). Other works include Nouvel essai sur la richesse des nations (1821) and Traité d’économie publique, suivi d’un aperçu sur les finances de France (1852).
[34] Ferrier, François Louis Auguste (1777-1861) was an advocate for protectionism and served as director general of the Customs Administration during the Empire and was a member of the Chamber of Peers during the July monarchy. His major works include Du gouvernement considéré dans ses rapports avec le commerce: Ou, De l"administration commerciale opposée à l"économie politique (1805, 1821).
[35] Constant, Commentaire sur l’ouvrage de Filangieri (1822). Seconde Partie. Chapitre IX. Du commerce des grains.
[36] In the meantime Charles Comte had married Say's daughter Adrienne on 4 February 1818.
[37] Traité de législation (1827). Its sequel Traité de la propriété was meant to follow soon afterwards but got delayed by the outbreak of Revolution in August 1830 and did not appear in print until 1834: Traité de la propriété (1834).
[38] Say, Œuvres complètes. Edited by André Tiran et al. (2002-). See, Leçons d’économie politique, vol. 4 of Œuvres complètes (2003), pp. 51-262.
[39] For Le Censeur européen Thierry wrote an article on "Factions" (class), and on the English revolution of the 17th century, and then later wrote histories of the French Third Estate (1853) and the conquest of England by the Normans (1825) from the perspective of liberal class analysis, although with an increasing ethnic or racial bent.
[40] Bastiat, Bastiat, "Introduction, Ce qu’on voit et ce qu’on ne voit pas (July 1850), See also CW3, p. 403.
[41] Leter lists 26 people in this generation of which I have selected five of the most important to discuss here. See the "Appendix: The Three Generations of the Paris School" for details.
[42] Lucette Levan-Lemesle, “Guillaumin, Éditeur d’Économie politique 1801-1864” (1985).
[43] Bastiat, Cobden et la ligue (1845), Sophismes économiques (1st series 1846, 2nd 1848), "The State" (JDD, 25 Sept. 1848), Harmonies économiques (1850, 1851), Ce que l"on voit et ce que l"on ne voit pas ou l"économie politique en une leçon (1850), and Bastiat and Proudhon, Gratuité du crédit (1850). On Bastiat, see Robert Leroux, Political Economy and Liberalism in France: The Contributions of Frédéric Bastiat (2011).
[44] Coquelin, Du Crédit et des Banques (1848), Coquelin et Guillaumin eds. Dictionnaire de l’Économie Politique (1852-1853). On Coquelin see, Philippe Nataf, “La vie et l’oeuvre de Charles Coquelin (1802-1852)” (2006).
[45] Chevalier, Cours d’économie fait au Collège de France. Année 1841-42, La liberté aux États-unis (1849).
[46] Garnier, Éléments de l’Économie politique (1846), editor of Annuaire de l"économie politique et de la statistique (1844), Richard Cobden, les ligueurs et la ligue (1846).
[47] Michel Leter was interested in describing the activities of the Paris School across the entire 19th century and so includes 23 individuals in total as comprising this generation. Only nine of these were old enough to have been active during the late July Monarchy and Second Republic. Of these, I have selected three of the most important to discuss here. See the "Appendix: The Three Generations of the Paris School" for details.
[48] Molinari, Études économiques. L"Organisation de la liberté industrielle et l"abolition de l"esclavage (1846), Histoire du tarif (1847), "De la production de la sécurité," JDE (Feb. 1849), Les Soirées de la rue Saint-Lazare (1849), Cours d'économie politique (1855). See the entry on "Molinari" in The Encyclopedia of Libertarianism, ed. Ronald Hamowy (2008), pp. 336-37; and Hart, "Gustave de Molinari and the Anti-Statist Liberal Tradition" (1981).
[49] Fonteyraud, Mélanges d’économie politique. La Ligue anglaise pour la liberté du commerce. Notice historique sur la vie et les travaux de Ricardo. Edited by J. Garnier. Paris: Guillaumin, 1853.
[50] Passy, De l"Instruction secondaire en France (Paris: Guillaumin, 1846); De l"Enseignement obligatoire, discussion entre M. G. de Molinari et M. Frédéric Passy (1859), De la propriété intellectuelle (1859), Notice biographique sur Frédéric Bastiat (1857). On Passy see Hart, "For Whom the Bell Tolls: The School of Liberty" (2017).
[51] See the "Appendix: The Three Generations of the Paris School" for details.
[52] On Dunoyer's life see the older biography by René Adenot, Les Idées Économiques et Politiques de Charles Dunoyer (1907); Anon., "Dunoyer," Dictionnaire de l"économie politique, vol. 1, pp. 622-3; "E.R." article "Dunoyer," Nouveau Dictionnaire d’économie politique (1891), vol. 1, p. 750; Liggio, Leonard P., "Charles Dunoyer and French Classical Liberalism" (1977); and David M. Hart, Class Analysis, Slavery and the Industrialist Theory of History in French Liberal Thought, 1814-1830: The Radical Liberalism of Charles Comte and Charles Dunoyer (1994); and the entry on "Dunoyer" in The Encyclopedia of Libertarianism (2008), pp. 129-30.
[53] See, "The Tax Authorities and Wine" (October, 1841) and "On the Allocation of the Land Tax in the Department of Les Landes” (July, 1844).
[54] See, Amable Charles comte de Franqueville, Le premier siècle de l"Institut de France (1896); and the Academy of Moral and Political Sciences website http://www.asmp.fr/sommaire.htm.
[55] It is instructive to compare developments in teaching political economy in France with what was happening in England. Malthus became Professor of History and Political Economy at the East India Company College in Hertfordshire in 1805. The Political Economy Club was founded by James Mill in 1821. Nassau Senior was appointed to the newly created Drummond Professorship of Political Economy at All Souls College, Oxford in 1825. J.R. McCulloch was the first professor of political economy at the newly founded University College London in 1828. George Pryme was the first Professor of Political Economy at the University of Cambridge in 1828.
[56] On teaching economics in France see, Lucette Le Van-Lemesle, "La promotion de l"économie politique en France au XIXe siècle" (1980); Martin S. Staum, "French Lecturers in Political Economy, 1815-1848: Varieties of liberalism" (1998); and Alain Alcouffe, "The Institutionalization of Political Economy in French Universities: 1819-1896" (1989).
[57] Rossi's lectures were published as Cours d’économie politique, 2 vols. (1839) and his articles collected in Mélanges d’économie politique, d’histoire et de philosophie, 2 vol. (1857). He was elevated to the French Peerage by Guizot in 1839 and eventually appointed Ambassador to the Vatican in 1845, where he was assassinated in 1848.
[58] Chevalier's lectures were published as M. Chevalier, Cours d’économie fait au Collège de France. Année 1841-42.
[59] Adolphe Blanqui, Cours d'économie industrielle (1838-39) (1838); Histoire d'économie politique en Europe, depuis les anciens jusqu"à nos jours (1837-38).
[60] Joseph T. Salerno, "The Neglect of Bastiat's School by English-Speaking Economists: A Puzzle Resolved" (2001).
[61] It should be noted that the Swiss-born land surveyor and translator Théodore Fix (1800-1846) made a false start in creating a journal dedicated to political economy. He and Adolphe Blanqui founded the Revue mensuelle d'économie politique (1833-36) which was initially influenced by Sismondi's paternalistic interventionism concerning support for the poor and working class but gradually turned in a more free market direction under the influence of Rossi and Blanqui. It was an important precursor to JDE but failed because it lacked the financial backing Guillaumin would be able to provide later. His only book was on the social question Observations sur l"état des classes ouvrières (1846).
[62] Minart, Gustave de Molinari, p. 56. The economist Henri Baudrillart called it “le centre et le lien de notre école” (the centre and connecting point of our school of thought). Henri Baudrillart is quoted in Joseph Garnier, “Guillaumin. Ses funérailes, - sa vie et son oeuvre” (JDE, 1865). Quote comes from p. 111. Lucette Levan-Lemesle, “Guillaumin, Éditeur d’Économie politique 1801-1864” (1985).
[63] The Guillaumin firm published 2,356 titles between its founding in 1837 and its take-over by Félix Alcan in 1906 at an average rate of 31.8 titles per year. In the last years of the July Monarchy 1837-1847 it published 156 books and pamphlets at a rate of 14 p.a.; during the Second Republic 1848-52 it published 204 titles at a rate of 41 p.a. Its peak year was 1848, the year of Revolution, during which it published 67 titles. See the list of publications compiled by Benoît Malbranque, "Liste complète des titres publiés par Guillaumin (1837-1910)" (2017).
[64] Michel Lutfalla, "Aux Origines du liberalisme economique en France: le Journal des Économistes; Analyse du contenu de la premiere serie, 1841-53" (1974).
[65] Breton, Yves. “The Société d’économie politique of Paris (1842–1914)” (2001).
[66] It was inspired by the success of J.R. McCulloch's A Dictionary, Practical, Theoretical and Historical of Commerce and Commercial Navigation (1832) and was designed to serve the specific needs of French businessmen and traders.
[67] The Journal des économistes was launched in December 1841 and appeared of the 15th of every month. The editors in our period were Gilbert-Urbain Guillaumin (December 1841), Adolphe Blanqui (1842-43), Hippolyte Dussard (1843-45), and Joseph Garnier (1845-55). It contained a combination of theoretical articles, analysis of current economic policy, book reviews, reports of debates in the Chamber of Deputies, and minutes of meetings of the Political Economy Society.
[68] The Annuaire appeared for 56 years until it ended in 1899.
[69] Fonteyraud edited the volume on Ricardo, translating some of his work for the first time into French and writing a very detailed introduction and notes. Molinari did the two last volumes in the series on Hume, Franklin, Bentham, and other 18th century authors.
[70] Rothbard coined the term "proto-Austrian" to describe J.B. Say but it also applies equally well to Bastiat. Rothbard, Classical Economics, p. 21.
[71] The French Free Trade Association was founded on 23 February 1846 in Bordeaux and then a National Association followed on 10 May based in Paris. Bastiat was the secretary of the Board, which was presided over by François d’Harcourt and having among its members Michel Chevalier, Auguste Blanqui, Joseph Garnier, Gustave de Molinari, and Horace Say. The journal of the Association was called Le Libre-Échange and was edited and largely written by Bastiat. The first issue appeared on 29 November 1846 and it closed on 16 April 1848 after 72 issues, when the economists decided to focus their attention on fighting the rise of socialism.
[72] The Congrès des Économistes was founded by the Belgian Free Trade Association and organised by Le Hardy de Beaulieu and Charles de Brouckère. A European-wide congress was held in Brussels in September 1847 which was attended by 170 people who were a "who's who" of the leading advocates of liberal political economy in Europe. It was attended by a large contingent from France, including Horace Say, Charles Dunoyer, Guillaumin, Joseph Garnier, Alcide Fonteyraud, the Duke d’Harcourt, Adolphe Blanqui, Louis Wolowski, and Gustave de Molinari. The Congress was also attended by Karl Marx but it is not known if he met any of the French political economists. See, Congrès des Économistes réunis à Bruxelles (1847). Attendee list pp. 5-9. The speech Marx intended to give at the Congress, but was not allowed to, can be found in Karl Marx Frederick Engels Collected Works, vol. 6 (2010),; Frederick Engels, "The Economic Congress", pp. 274-78, Karl Marx, "The Protectionists, the Free Traders and the Working Class," pp. 279-81, Frederick Engels, "The Free Trade Congress at Brussels," pp. 282-90.
[73] The third Friends of Peace Congress was held in Paris in August 1849 (22-24th) chaired by the novelist Victor Hugo and where Bastiat gave an important speech "Disarmament, Taxes, and the Influence of Political Economy on the Peace Movement." Molinari and Coquelin formally represented the Political Economy Society at the Congress, Molinari wrote a detailed report on its proceedings for the JDE, and Joseph Garnier edited the proceedings which were published by Guillaumin. Garnier, Joseph. Congrès des amis de la paix universelle (1850). Molinari, “Le Congrès de la paix, à Paris” (JDE, 1849).
[74] Mme Hortense Cheuvreux (née Girard) (1808-93) was married to the wealthy textile manufacturer Pierre-Casimir Cheuvreux (1797-1881) who was a major funder of the economists's activities. Their luxurious home in Paris was where Mme Cheuvreux's salons were held. Bastiat with his "Rabelaisian" wit, prodigious memory for literature, and musical skills (he played the cello) was a star attraction, along with the scientist Ampère, the priest Gratry, and Alexis de Tocqueville. Twenty seven years after his death Hortense Cheuvreux published a volume of Bastiat's letters to her in which some of these events are described, Bastiat, Lettres d’un habitant des Landes (1877).
[75] Dictionnaire de l’économie politique, Coquelin and Guillaumin, eds. (1852–53).
[76] Nouveau Dictionnaire d’Économie Politique, eds. Léon Say and Joseph Chailley (1891-92).
[77] Molinari would write a scathing book about Louis Napoléon's economic views in Napoleon III publiciste (1861).
[78] Chevalier, La liberté aux États-unis (Paris: Capelle, 1849).
[79] He edited and annotated the Guillaumin edition of Malthus's book which appeared in 1845 as well as a second edition in 1852 with a long Foreword defending Malthus against his critics. Garnier wrote the biographical article on “Malthus” and a long entry on “Population” (which was an extended defense of Malthusianism) for the DEP (1852-53). He also published a condensed version of Malthus" On the Principle of Population in 1857 with copious commentaries and many appendices.
[80] See, the “Beacon for Freedom of Expression” database of banned books and the entry for the DEP http://search.beaconforfreedom.org/search/censored_publications/publication.html?id=9709582.
[81] Bastiat first made the contrast between "extra-legal" and "legal plunder" in the essay “Justice et fraternité” (15 June 1848, JDE) in CW2, p. 71 and then in “The Law” (June 1850) in CW2, p. 116.
[82] Bastiat used several terms to describe the elites who benefited from tariffs and subsides, such as "l’oligarchie anglaise" (the English oligarchy) (used many times in his first book Cobden et la ligue (1845)), “la classe privilégiée” (the privileged class), “la classe spoliatrice” (the plundering class).
[83] For the historic al background of the struggle over tariffs, see David Todd, Free Trade and its Enemies in France, 1814–1851 (2015).
[84] Charles Dupin, Le petit producteur français, Volume 4: “Le petit commerçant français” (1827).
[85] Prosper Duvergier de Hauranne, Discours sur les céréales (1832).
[86] Alcide Fonteyraud, article "La ligue anglaise" in Revue britannique (Jan. 1846).
[87] François Eugène Gabriel duc d'Harcourt, Discours en faveur de la liberté du commerce, prononcés à la Chambre des Pairs et à la Chambre des Députés (1846).
[88] Joseph Garnier, Richard Cobden, les ligueurs et la ligue, précis de l"histoire de la dernière révolution économique et financière en Angleterre (1846).
[89] Charles Dunoyer, "Influence du régime prohibitif sur les relations sociales et sur le développement des diverses industries" (JDE 1843; "De l"agitation anglaise pour la liberté commerciale" (JDE 1845).
[90] Gustave de Molinari, Histoire du tarif (1847). Vol. 1: Les fers et les houilles; vol. 2: Les céréales. Molinari would also write the key articles on free trade in the DEP: Céréales, T. 1, pp. 301-26; “Liberté des échanges (Associations pour la)” DEP, vol. 2, p. 45-49; Liberté du commerce, liberté des échanges, T. 2, pp. 49-63; Tarifs de douane, T. 2, pp. 712-16; and “Union douanière” (Customs Union), DEP, vol. 2, p. 788-89.
[91] Bastiat, "Déclaration de principes (Association pour la liberté des échanges))", 10 May, 1846; reprinted in Libre-Échange, 25 Apr. 1847, no. 22, p. 169; along with the Association's new programme. Reprinted in Bastiat, Oeuvres complètes, vol. 2, pp. 1-4.
[92] See for example, Alphonse de Lamartine, Discours de M. de Lamartine, dans l’Assemblée marseillaise du Libre échange, le 24 août 1847 (1847).
[93] Their statement of principles can be found in Association pour la défense du travail national, Examen des théories du libre-échange et des résultats du système protecteur (1847).
[94] Blanc, “Conclusion. De quelle manière on pourrait, selon nous, organiser le travail” in Louis Blanc, Organisation du travail. Association universelle. Ouvriers. - Chefs d’ateliers. - Hommes de lettres. (1841), pp. 76-93.
[95] Reprinted in Louis Blanc, Organisation du travail (5ème édition) (1847). “Réponses à diverses objections.” Chevalier’s article, pp. 121-35; and Blanc’s response from 17 Feb. 1845, pp. 135-48.
[96] Dunoyer, La Liberté du travail, vol. 1, Chap. X. "Post-scriptum sur les objections qu’on a soulevées, dans ces derniers temps, contre le régime de la libre concurrence," pp. 408-71.
[97] See the collection of revolutionary wall posters in Les murailles révolutionnaires (1856) which contains a poster for the French Free Trade Association on "La vie à bon marché" (1856), vol. 1, p. 352; an advertisement for a meeting of the "Club de la liberté du travail," vol. 2, p. 475; and an appeal to voters in the Département de la Seine by Charles Coquelin, vol. 2, pp. 685-86.
[98] “A Few Words about the Title of our Journal” (La République française, 26 February 1848), in CW3, pp. 524-26. See also “Bastiat the Revolutionary Journalist and Politician,” in the Introduction to CW3, pp. lxviii-lxxiii.
[99] See the collection by Malbranque and Hart: Bastiat and Molinari. Jacques Bonhomme: L’éphémère journal de Frédéric Bastiat et Gustave de Molinari (2014).
[100] The original short version was "The State (draft)" (JB, 11 June 1848), in CW2, pp.105-6. An expanded version appeared later in the Journal des débats: "The State" (JDD, 25 Sept. 1848), in CW2, pp. 93-104. Bastiat was an eyewitness to some of the bloody events on the streets of Paris and reported what he saw in letters to his friends. See 93. Letter to Mme Marsan (27 February 1848), CW 1, p. 142; 104. Letter to Mme Marsan (29 June 1848), CW 1, pp. 156-7; both of which are discussed in “Bastiat the Revolutionary Journalist and Politician,” in the Introduction to CW3, pp. lxviii-lxxiii.
[101] The Paris economists had had a chance to engage with Marx personally when he and Engels attended the "Congress of Economists" in Brussels in September 1847. He was listed on the program as a speaker but according to the editors of the Marx Engels Collected Works, his session was cancelled by the organisers after the speaker before Marx, Georg Weerth (also a socialist), had offended them. See MECW Volume 38, footnote on p. 162. Given the wild ad hominem attacks in the draft of Marx's speech printed in the MECW it is perhaps not surprising. We have no information about this incident from the economists" perspective. We also have no information about members of the "Club Lib" meeting with Marx or other members of his Club but the possibility that they might have is an intriguing one.
[102] Leter says that among its members and participants were Michel Chevalier, Léon Faucher, Adolphe Blanqui, Frédéric Bastiat, and Louis Wolowski, Leter, "Étude de l’école de Paris," p. 466.
[103] Molinari, "Obituary of Joseph Garnier" (JDE, October 1881). Molinari tells a similar story in his obituary of Coquelin with the added detail that the economists chose not to fight back and so let the communists win by not throwing a single punch to defend themselves: Molinari, “ Charles Coquelin” (JDE, Septembre et Octobre 1852), p. 172.
[104] In the elections of 23 April 1848 a number of economists got elected, such as Bastiat (Les Landes), Léon Faucher (Marne), Louis Wolowski (La Seine), and some supporters of economic deregulation, such as the poet and song writer Béranger, Gustave de Beaumont (La Somme), Prosper de Hauranne, Louis Reybaud, and Alexis de Tocqueville.
[105] Léon Faucher, Du droit au travail (1848) and Du système de M. Louis Blanc ou le travail, l"association et l’impôt (1848).
[106] Michel Chevalier, Lettres sur l’Organisation du travail (1848) and Question des travailleurs (1848).
[107] The speeches were collected in Le droit au travail à l"Assemblée nationale. Recueil complet de tous les discours prononcés dans cette mémorable discussion. ed. M. Joseph Garnier (1848). Tocqueville's speech can be found on pp. 99-113.
[108] Molinari, “Introduction à la huitième année,” JDE, December 1848, T. 28, p. 3.
[109] Molinari, "Obituary of Joseph Garnier" (JDE 1881), p. 9.
[110] Alcide Fonteyraud, , "Le droit au travail à l’Assemblée nationale," JDE, février 1849, T. 22, no. 95, p. 337.
[111] Molinari, Les Soirées de la rue Saint-Lazare (1849). He would return to this popular format with two more books in 1855 and 1886: Conservations familières sur le commerce des grains (1855) and Conversations sur le commerce des grains et la protection de l’agriculture (1886). In both the conversations are limited to the trade in grain.
[112] Henri Alcide Fonteyraud and Louis Wolowski No. 92, “Principes d’économie politique” (1850).
[113] I have reconstructed the budgets for 1848-49 from data in Alphonse Courtois, "Le budget de 1848" in the Annuaire de l"économie politique et de la statistique pour 1848 (1848), pp. 29-51; and Alphonse Courtois, "Le budget de 1849" in Annuaire de l"économie politique et de la statistique pour 1850 (1850), pp. 18-28. See, “French Government’s Budgets for Fiscal Years 1848 and 1849,” in Appendix 4, in CW3, pp. 509-16.
[114] See his speeches in the Chamber, “Speech on Postal Reform” (24 August 1848); “Speaks in a Discussion on a Proposal to change the tariff on imported salt” (11 Jan. 1849): and “Speech on the Tax on Wines and Spirits" (12 Dec. 1849).
[115] See, “The Utopian" (January 1847), CW2, p. 194, and Chapter 2 "Dismissing Members of the Armed Forces" in the pamphlet What is Seen and What is Not Seen (July 1850), CW2, p. 408.
[116] He describes it as "The first species of military taxation that I meet with is, that which is called, according to circumstances, conscription or recruitment." See, Bastiat’s Speech on “Disarmament and Taxes” (August 1849), in CW2, p. 527.
[117] Garnier, Congrès des amis de la paix universelle réuni à Paris en 1849 (1850)
[118] Bastiat’s Speech on “Disarmament and Taxes” (August 1849), in CW2, p. 529.
[119] François Arago, Sur les Fortifications de Paris (1841) and Études sur les fortifications de Paris, considérées politiquement et militairement (1845).
[120] Michel Chevalier, Les fortifications de Paris, lettre à M. Le Comte Molé (1841) and Cours d’Économie politique fait au Collège de France par Michel Chevalier (1851), vol. 2, “Douzième leçon. Concours de l’armée française aux travaux des fortifications de Paris,” pp. 183-96.
[121] Patricia O"Brien, “L’Embastillement de Paris: The Fortification of Paris during the July Monarchy” (1975).
[122] See, “Bastiat's Invention of ‘Crusoe Economics’,” in the Introduction to CW3, pp. lxiv-lxvii, and “Human Action” in Further Aspects of Bastiat’s Thought, CW4 (forthcoming).
[123] Proudhon, Banque du peuple (1849).
[124] A full list of his writings can be found in Nataf, “La vie et l’oeuvre de Charles Coquelin (1802–1852)," pp. 526-30.
[125] Courcelle-Seneuil, Traité théorique et pratique des opérations de banque (1853), and La Banque libre, exposé des fonctions du commerce de banque (1867).
[126] Dunoyer, L"Industrie et la Morale (1825), p. 366. In 1849 Dunoyer had become more conservative on this issue as his remarks in the meeting of the Political Economy Society where they discussed Molinari's book reveal.
[127] Destutt de Tracy, Commentaire sur l’esprit des lois de Montesquieu (1819), pp. 263-66.
[128] J.-B. Say, Œuvres complètes, vol. 4 : Leçons d’économie politique (2003), pp. 101-2.
[129] Molinari, “Le droit électorale,” Courrier français, 23 juillet 1846. Reprinted in Questions d'économie politique et de droit public (1861), vol. 2, pp. 271-73. On others who thought in a similar way, like Louis Graslin and Émile de Girardin, see Faccarello, "Bold Ideas. French liberal economists and the state" (2010).
[130] He referred to “une Compagnie d’actionnaires” (a company owned by shareholders) (p. 355), “une Compagnie d’assurance” (an insurance company) (p. 318), and “une Compagnie d’assurance mutuelle” (a mutual insurance company) (p. 353). All references to Thiers, De la propriété (1848).
[131] Molinari, "De la production de la sécurité” (1849), pp. 288-89.
[132] Molinari, Les Soirées, p. 331.
[133] This was the first of three meetings of the Political Economy Society on the proper limits to the power of the state which Molinari's book provoked and it was followed by similar discussions in January and February 1850. The first meeting was followed in November by a critical review by Coquelin in the JDE. The minutes of these meetings have been translated and will appear in CW4 (forthcoming). See Part 1 in “Chronique,” JDE, T. 24, no. 103, Oct. 1849, pp. 315-16; Part 2 in “Chronique,” JDE, 15 Jan. 1850, T. XXV, pp. 202-205; and Part 3 in “Chronique,” JDE, T. XXV, no. 107, 15 fev., 1850, pp. 202-5.
[134] See, Cours d'économie politique, vol. 2, "Quatrième partie: De la consommation." Onzième leçon, “Le revenu. La consommation utile et la consommation nuisible,” pp. 427-79; Douzième leçon, “Les consommations publiques,” pp. 480-534 where he discusses what he calls “la concurrence politique" (political competition); and L"évolution politique et la Révolution, Chap. X “Les Gouvernements de l’avenir,” pp. 351-423.
[135] See, “Ceteris Paribus” in Further Aspects of Bastiat’s Thought, CW4 (forthcoming).
[136] Fontenay, EH2, pp. 454-64.
[137] See his discussion of rent in EH chapter IX "Landed Property" and chapter XIII "On Rent".
[138] See EH chapter VIII "Private Property and Community."
[139] See the criticism of Bastiat's theory levelled by his colleagues in Bastiat, “Comments at a Meeting of the Political Economy Society on State Support for popularising Political Economy, his idea of Land Rent in Economic Harmonies, the Tax on Alcohol, and Socialism” (JDE 10 Dec. 1849).
[140] See, “Harmony and Disharmony” and “Disturbing and Restorative Factors” in Further Aspects of Bastiat’s Thought, CW4 (forthcoming).
[141] Carey originally accused Bastiat of plagiarising his work but later withdrew the charge when he realised they had been working independently of each other.
[142] See his plans which he expressed in ES2 1 "The Physiology of Plunder" (c. 1847), in CW3, pp. 113-30.
[143] Anthony de Jasay, "Thirty-five Hours," Library of Economics and Liberty (Econlib), July 15, 2002 http://www.econlib.org/library/Columns/Jasaywork.html.
[144] "What Is Seen and What Is Not Seen" (July 1850), in CW3, pp. 401-52. Chapter 1 "The Broken Window," pp. 405-7.
[145] Bastiat rejects Henri Storch's view about value being dependent upon "judgement" even though it seems very close to his own idea about "evaluation" by individuals. The same goes for his rejection of Condillac's argument that both parties "profit" from an exchange. See, EH, Chap. V "On Value".
[146] As an example of his use of the term "evaluated" see "En général, les échanges de services sont déterminés et évalués par l’intérêt personnel" (in general, the exchanges of services are determined and evaluated out of self-interest) in EH Chap. V "On Value."
[147] See, “Human Action” in Further Aspects of Bastiat’s Thought, CW4 (forthcoming).
[148] Marx, "I do not claim to have discovered either the existence of classes in modern society or the struggle between them. Long before me, bourgeois historians had described the historical development of this struggle between the classes, as had bourgeois economists their economic anatomy." "Letter to Joseph Weydemeyer (5 March 1852), in MECW Volume 39, p. 58. Quoted on title page of Hart et al., Social Class and State Power (2018).
[149] See the note above on the use of "plunder" in "The Law" and "Property and Plunder."
[150] See his essay "The State (draft)" (JB, 11 June 1848), in CW2, pp.105-6; and "The State" (JDD, 25 Sept. 1848), in CW2, pp. 93-104. His definition of the state is on p. 97.
[151] Molinari, Les Révolutions et le despotisme envisagés au point de vue des intérêts matériel (1852) which was a speech given at the Musée de l"Industrie in Brussels (4 October, 1852), pp. 135-36.
[152] Molinari, "Les Révolutions et le despotisme envisagés au point de vue des intérêts matériel (October 1852)," p. 116.
[153] Larry Siedentop, "The Two Liberal Traditions" (1979).
[154] Siedentop, "The Two Liberal Traditions," p.153. The liberals whom Siedentop identifies as the "originators of a sociological approach to political theory" included Madame de Staël, Benjamin Constant, the group known as the "Doctrinaires" which included Royer-Collard, Barante, and Guizot, and, most importantly, Alexis de Tocqueville. I believe it applies even more to the members of the Paris School of political economists discussed here.
[155] See, Charles Gide, Principes d'économie politique (1884) and Alfred Marshall, Principles of Economics (1890).
[156] Bastiat, Social fallacies by Frederic Bastiat (1944) and Harmonies of Political Economy (1944–1945).
[157] Ralph Raico, The Place of Religion in the Liberal Philosophy of Constant, Tocqueville, and Lord Acton (1970), and Ralph Raico, “The Centrality of French liberalism” (2012). Also, Leonard P. Liggio, Dunoyer and the Bourbon Restoration of 1814–15 (no date), and Leonard P. Liggio, “Charles Dunoyer and French Classical Liberalism” (1977).
[158] Salerno, “The Neglect of the French Liberal School in Anglo-American Economics: A Critique of Received Explanations” (1988); "The Neglect of Bastiat's School by English-Speaking Economists: A Puzzle Resolved" (2001). Jörg Guido Hülsmann, “Bastiat’s Legacy in Economics” (2001).
[159] Robert Leroux, Lire Bastiat: Science sociale et libéralisme (2008); Political Economy and Liberalism in France: The Contributions of Frédéric Bastiat (2011); The Foundations of Industrialism: Charles Comte, Charles Dunoyer and Liberal Thought in France (2016).
[160] Hart, "Gustave de Molinari and the Anti-Statist Liberal Tradition" (1981), Class Analysis, Slavery and the Industrialist Theory of History in French Liberal Thought, 1814-1830 (1994), and others in the bibliography.
[161] Liberty Fund has the following works by the Paris School in print or in progress: Destutt de Tracy, A Treatise on Political Economy; Benjamin Constant, Principles of Politics Applicable to a all Governments; Benjamin Constant, Commentary on Filangieri’s Work; Benjamin Constant, On Religion; Bastiat, The Collected Works of Frédéric Bastiat. In Six Volumes; and Molinari, Evenings on Saint-Lazarus Street.
[162] Florin Aftalion, "Introduction," Frédéric Bastiat, Oeuvres économiques (1983); Pierre Garello (ed.), Journal des Économistes et des Études Humaines, vol. 11, no. 2/3 (Jun 2001). Editor-in-Chief: Garello, Pierre. Special issue devoted to papers given at the Bastiat bicentennial conference; Nataf, Philippe. “La vie et l’oeuvre de Charles Coquelin (1802-1852)” (2006).
[163] Michel Leter, “Éléments pour une étude de l’École de Paris (1803-1852)" (2006); "Préface: Frédéric Bastiat et les fondements littéraires de l"analyse économique," Bastiat, Sophismes économiques (2004, 2009), pp. 7-38; "Préface," Pamphlets (2004, 2009), pp. 7-31.
[164] See for example, Yves Breton et Michel Lutfalla (eds.), L"économie politique en France au XIXème siècle, (1991); Alain Madelin ed., Aux sources du modèle libéral français (1997); Philippe Nemo et Jean Petitot ed., Histoire de libéralisme en Europe (2006); and Les penseurs libéraux, eds. Alain Laurent et Vincent Valentin (2012); Gilbert Faccarello, “Bold ideas. French liberal economists and the State: Say to Leroy-Beaulieu” (2010).
[165] Minart, Gérard. Frédéric Bastiat (1801-1850). Le croisé de libre-échange (2004); Jean-Baptiste Say (1767-1832). Maître et pédagogue de l’école française d’économie politique libérale (2005); and Gustave de Molinari (1819-1912), pour un gouvernement à bon marché dans un milieu libre (2012).
[166] Frédéric Bastiat, Oeuvres complètes. Édition en 7 volumes, sous la direction de Jacques de Guenin. (Paris: Institut Charles Coquelin, 2009-).
[167] J.B. Say, Œuvres complètes. Edited by André Tiran et al. (2006). With a companion volume on Say, Poitier, Jean-Pierre and André Tiran, eds. Jean-Baptiste Say: Nouveau regards sur son oeuvre (2003).
[168] Molinari, "Les Révolutions et le despotisme envisagés au point de vue des intérêts matériel" (October 1852), p. 151.
[169] Benoît Malbranque, "Liste complète des titres publiés par Guillaumin (1837-1910)", Institut Coppet (janvier 2, 2017), https://www.institutcoppet.org/2017/01/02/liste-complete-titres-publies-guillaumin-1837-1910.
Les murailles révolutionnaires: Collection complète des Professions de foi, Affiches, Décrets, Bulletins de la République, Facsimile de signatures. (Paris et les Départements). Illustrées des portraits des membres du Gouvernement provisoire, des principaux chefs des Clubs, des Rédacteurs et Gérants des premiers journaux de la Révolution (Paris: Chez J. Bry (ainé), Édit., 1852). A second edition appeared in 1856 with 2 vols.
Report of the Proceedings of the Second General Peace Congress, held in Paris, on the 22nd, 23rd and 24th of August, 1849. Compiled from Authentic Documents, under the Superintendence of the Peace Congress Committee. (London: Charles Gilpin, 5, Bishopsgate Street Without, 1849).
François Arago, Sur les Fortifications de Paris (Paris: Bachelier, 1841).
François Arago, Études sur les fortifications de Paris, considérées politiquement et militairement (Paris: Pagnerre, 1845).
Association pour la défense du travail national, Examen des théories du libre-échange et des résultats du système protecteur. (15 janvier 1847.) (Paris: imp. de A. Guyot, 1847).
Bastiat, The Collected Works of Frédéric Bastiat. In Six Volumes (Indianapolis: Liberty Fund, 2011-), General Editor Jacques de Guenin. Academic Editor Dr. David M. Hart.
Frédéric Bastiat, Oeuvres complètes. Édition en 7 volumes, sous la direction de Jacques de Guenin. (Paris: Institut Charles Coquelin, 2009-).
Bastiat, Oeuvres complètes de Frédéric Bastiat, mises en ordre, revues et annotées d’après les manuscrits de l’auteur. Deuxième Édition. Ed. Prosper Paillottet and with a "Notice sur la vie et les écrits de Frédéric Bastiat" by Roger de Fontenay. (Paris: Guillaumin, 1862-64).
Bastiat, "The Tax Authorities and Wine" (October, 1841), in CW2, pp. 10-23.
Bastiat, "On the Allocation of the Land Tax in the Department of Les Landes” (July, 1844), in CW4 (forthcoming).
Bastiat, Frédéric, “Sur l’ouvrage de M. Dunoyer: La liberté du travail” (May 1845), in Œuvres complètes, t. I, (Paris: Guillaumin, 1855), p. 428–433. Translated in CW4 (forthcoming).
Bastiat, Cobden et la ligue, ou l"Agitation anglaise pour la liberté du commerce (Paris: Guillaumin, 1845).
Bastiat, Sophismes économiques (Paris: Guillaumin, 1st series 1846, 2nd series 1848).
Bastiat, "On Population" (De la population), JDE, 15 Oct., 1846, T. XV, no. 59, pp. 217-234.
Bastiat, ed. Le Libre-échange: Journal du travail agricole, industriel et commercial. Journal of the Association pour la liberté des échanges (29 November 1846 - 16 April 1848). 72 issues appeared. Edited by Bastiat until 13 February 1848, then by Charles Coquelin.
Frédéric Bastiat, "Justice et Fraternité” (Journal des Économistes,15 juin 1848), translation in Collected Works of Frédéric Bastiat (Liberty Fund, 2012), vol. 2, pp. 60-81.
Bastiat, “A Few Words about the Title of our Journal” (La République française, 26 February 1848), in CW3, pp. 524-26.
Bastiat, "The State (draft)" (JB, 11 June 1848), in CW2, pp.105-6. An expanded version appeared later in the Journal des débats: "The State" (JDD, 25 Sept. 1848), in CW2, pp. 93-104.
Bastiat and Molinari. Jacques Bonhomme: L’éphémère journal de Frédéric Bastiat et Gustave de Molinari (11 juin – 13 juillet 1848). Recueil de tous les articles, augmenté d’une introduction. Ed. Benoît Malbranque (Paris: Institut Coppet, 2014).
Bastiat, “Speech on Postal Reform”. Speech to the National Constituent Assembly, 24 August 1848 in CW4 (forthcoming).
Bastiat, "Natural and Artificial Organisation" (Organisation naturelle Organisation artificielle), JDE, T. XIX, No. 74, Jan 1848, pp. 113-26.
Bastiat, “Economic Harmonies: I., II., and III. The Needs of Man” (Harmonies économiques. I, II, III . Des besoins de l’homme), JDE, T. XXI, No. 87, 1 Sept. 1848, pp. 105-20; also in EH 1-3. And “Economic Harmonies IV” (Harmonies économiques. IV) JDE, T. XXII, No. 93, 15 Dec. 1848, pp. 7-18; also in EH 4.
Bastiat, "A Speech on "Disarmament, Taxes, and the Influence of Political Economy on the Peace Movement." A speech at the Friends of Peace Conference in Paris, 22 Aug., 1849. A short version is in French in Joseph Garnier, Congrès des amis de la paix universelle réuni à Paris en 1849, pp. 25-26; a longer longer version in English in Report of the Proceedings of the Second General Peace Congress, held in Paris, on the 22nd, 23rd and 24th of August, 1849 (translator unknown), pp. 49-52. It is untitled in both versions so we have given it one. Translated in CW3, pp. 526-32.
Bastiat, “Speaks in a Discussion on a Proposal to change the tariff on imported salt”. Short speech to the National Constituent Assembly, 11 Jan. 1849, in CW4 (forthcoming).
Bastiat, “Speech on the Tax on Wines and Spirits" (Discours sur l’impôt des boissons). Speech given in the Legislative Assembly on 12 Dec. 1849, in CW2.16, pp. 328-47.
Bastiat, “Comments at a Meeting of the Political Economy Society on State Support for popularising Political Economy, his idea of Land Rent in Economic Harmonies, the Tax on Alcohol, and Socialism” (10 Dec. 1849), In “Chronique,” JDE, 15 Dec. 1849, T. XXV, pp. 110-112, in CW4 (forthcoming).
Bastiat, Harmonies économiques, par M. Fr. Bastiat. Membre correspondant de l’Institut, Représentant du People à l’Assemblée Législative (Paris: Guillaumin, 1850).
Bastiat, Harmonies économiques. 2me édition. Augmentée des manuscrits laissés par l’auteur. Publiée par la Société des amis de Bastiat. (Paris: Guillaumin, 1851).
Frédéric Bastiat, La Loi (Paris: Guillaumin, 1850); translation "The Law" (June 1850), in CW2, pp. 107-46.
Bastiat, Ce qu"on voit et ce qu"on ne voit pas, ou l"Économie politique en une leçon. Par M. F. Bastiat, Représentant du peuple à l"Assemblée nationale, Membre correspondant de l"Institut (Paris: Guillaumin, 1850).
Bastiat, What Is Seen and What Is Not Seen (July 1850), in CW3, pp. 401-52.
Bastiat, Social fallacies by Frederic Bastiat, translated from the 5th ed. of the French by Patrick James Stirling, with a foreword by Rose Wilder Lane (Santa Ana, Calif.: Register Publishing Co., 1944).
Bastiat, Harmonies of Political Economy, trans. Patrick James Stirling (Santa Ana, Calif.: Register Pub., 1944–1945). 2 vols, which also included The Law.
Bastiat, Lettres d’un habitant des Landes, Frédéric Bastiat. Edited by Mme Cheuvreux (Paris: A. Quantin, 1877).
Louis Blanc, Organisation du travail (Paris: Prévot, 1840). 1st ed. 1839.
Louis Blanc, Organisation du travail. Association universelle. Ouvriers. - Chefs d’ateliers. - Hommes de lettres. (Paris: Administration de librairie, 1841. First edition 1839).
Louis Blanc, Organisation du travail (5ème édition), revue, corrigée et augmentée d'une polémique entre M. Michel Chevalier et l"auteur, ainsi que d'un appendice indiquant ce qui pourrait être tenté dès à présent (Paris: au bureau de la Société de l"industrie fraternelle, 1847). “Réponses à diverses objections.” Chevalier’s article, pp. 121-35; and Blanc’s response from 17 Feb. 1845, pp. 135-48.
Adolphe Blanqui, ed. Encyclopédie du commerçant. Dictionnaire du commerce et des marchandises, 2 vols. (Paris: Guillaumin, 1837-39).
Adolphe Blanqui, Cours d'économie industrielle (1838-39). Recueilli et annoté par Ad. Blaise et Joseph Garnier (Paris: L. Mathias, 1838).
Adolphe Blanqui, Histoire d'économie politique en Europe, depuis les anciens jusqu"à nos jours; suivie d'une bibliographie raisonnée des principaux ouvrages d'économie politique (Paris: Guillaumin, 1837-38), 2 vols. 1st ed. 1837 (one of the first three books ever published by Guillaumin). 2nd ed. 1842, 3rd. 1845, 4th revised ed. 1860.
Adolphe Blanqui, Des classes ouvrières en France pendant l"année 1848 (Paris: Pagnerre, 1849).
Maurice Block, Les progrès de la science économique depuis Adam Smith. Revision des doctrines économiques, 2 vols. (Paris: Guillaumin, 1890).
Pierre de Boisguilbert, Économistes financiers du XVIIIe siècle. Vauban, Projet d'une dîme royale. Boisguillebert, Détail de la France, Factum de la France, et opuscules divers. Jean Law, Considérations sur le numéraire et le commerce. Mémoires et lettres sur les banques, opuscules divers. Melon, Essai politique sur le commerce. Dutot, Réflexions politiques sur le commerce et les finances. Précédés de notices historiques sur chaque auteur, et accompagnés de commentaires et de notes explicatives, par M. Eugène Daire (Paris: Guillaumin, 1843). Collection des principaux économistes, vol. 1.
Louis Napoléon Bonaparte, Extinction du Paupérisme (Paris: Pagnerre, 1844).
Richard Cantillon, Essai sur la nature du commerce en général. Traduit de l"anglois. (Londres, chez Fletcher Gyles, dans Holborn, 1755).
Richard Cantillon, Essai sur la Nature du Commerce en General, edited with an English translation and other material by Henry Higgs, C.B. (Reissued for The Royal Economic Society by Frank Cass and Co., LTD., London. 1959). Online: http://oll.libertyfund.org/titles/285.
Henry Charles Carey, The Harmony of Interests agricultural, manufacturing, and commercial (Philadelphia: J. S. Skinner, 1851).
Michel Chevalier, Cours d’économie fait au Collège de France. Année 1841-42. Deux discours d’ouverture (Paris: Capelle, 1842).
Michel Chevalier, Les fortifications de Paris, lettre à M. Le Comte Molé (Paris: Charles Gosselin, 1841).
Michel Chevalier, Lettres sur l’Organisation du travail, ou études sur les principales causes de la misère et sur les moyens proposées pour y remédier (Paris: Capelle, 1848.
Michel Chevalier, Question des travailleurs : l"amélioration du sort des ouvriers, les salaires, l"organisation du travail (Paris: Hachette, 1848).
Michel Chevalier, La liberté aux États-unis (Paris: Capelle, 1849).
Chevalier, L"économie politique et le socialisme. Discours prononcé au Collège de France, le 28 février 1849, pour la récouverture du Cours d’économie politique (Paris:Capelle, 1849).
Michel Chevalier, Cours d’Économie politique fait au Collège de France par Michel Chevalier (Bruxelles: Meline, Cans, 1851). 2 vols.
Ambroise Clément, Recherches sur les causes de l’indigence (Paris: Guillaumin, 1846).
Ambroise Clément, "De la spoliation légale," JDE, 1e juillet 1848, T. 20, no. 83, pp. 363-74.
Congrès des Économistes réunis à Bruxelles, par les soins de l’Association belge pour la liberté commercial. Session de 1847. Séances des 16, 17 et 18 septembre. (Bruxelles: Imprimerie de Deltombe, 1847).
Charles Comte and Charles Dunoyer, Le Censeur, ou examen des actes et des ouvrages qui tendent à détruire ou à consolider la constitution de l"état. 7 volumes 1814-1815, (Paris: Marchant, 1814-15). Volume 1 by Comte alone, vols. 2-7 by Comte and Dunoyer. The dates of the volumes are as follows: volume 1, 12 June, 1814; vol. 2, Nov 15, 1814; vol. 3, Dec 20, 1814; vol. IV, March 1, 1815; vol. V, April 18, 1815; vol. VI, June 1, 1815; vol. VII, Sept 6, 1815. Place of publication for various editions given as 10 rue Git-le-Coeur and 38 rue des Notre-Dames-des-Victoires.
Charles Comte and Charles Dunoyer, Le Censeur européen, ou examen de diverses questions de droit public, et des divers ouvrages littéraires et scientifiques, considérés dans leurs rapports avec le progrès de la civilisation (Paris: bureau de l"administration, 1817-1819). 12 volumes. The journal had the motto of "Paix et liberté." Le Censeur européen appeared in 12 volumes from February 1817 until April 17, 1819.
Comte, Charles, De l’impossibilité d’établir une monarchie constitutionnelle sous un chef militaire et particulièrement Napoléon (Paris: Les marchands de nouveauté, 1815).
Charles Comte, articles in Le Censeur européen:
Comte, Charles, Traité de législation, ou exposition des lois générales suivant lesquelles les peuples prospèrent, dépérissent ou restent stationnaire, 4 vols. (Paris: A. Sautelet et Cie, 1827).
Comte, Charles, Traité de la propriété, 2 vols. (Paris: Chamerot, Ducollet, 1834).
Comte, Charles, “Notice historique sur la vie et les ouvrages de J.-B. Say”, in J.-B. Say, Mélanges et correspondance d’économie politique (Brussels, J.P. Meline, 1834).
Étienne Bonnot de Condillac, Le Commerce et le gouvernement considérés relativement l"un a l"autre: ouvrage elementaire (Paris; l"Imprimerie de P. Catineau An VII (1798)).
Étienne Bonnot, Abbé de Condillac, Commerce and Government Considered in their Mutual Relationship, translated by Shelagh Eltis, with an Introduction to His Life and Contribution to Economics by Shelagh Eltis and Walter Eltis (Indianapolis: Liberty Fund, 2008).
Victor Prosper Considerant, Théorie du droit de propriété et du droit au travail (1st ed.1845; Paris: Librairie phalanstérienne, 1848. 3rd ed.).
Constant, Benjamin, Écrits politiques. Ed. Marcel Gauchet (Paris, Gallimard, 1997).
Benjamin Constant, De l"esprit de conquête et de l"usurpation, dans leurs rapports avec la civilisation européene. Troisiéme édition, revue et augmentée. (Paris: Le Normant, 1814).
Benjamin Constant, Principles of Politics Applicable to a all Governments, trans. Dennis O’Keeffe, ed. Etienne Hofmann, Introduction by Nicholas Capaldi (Indianapolis: Liberty Fund, 2003).
Constant, "De la liberté de l"industrie" (1818) in Collection complète des ouvrages publiées sur le gouvernement représentatif et la Constitution actuelle de la France, formant une espèce de ouCourse de politique constitutionnelle. Première volume. Première Partie. (Paris: P. Plancher, 1818). vol. 1, pp. 358-83.
Constant, Benjamin, "De la liberté des anciens comparée à celles des modernes." Discours prononcé à l"Athénée royal de Paris en 1819 in Collection complète des ouvrages publiées sur le gouvernement représentatif et la constitution actuelle, ou Course de politique constitutionnelle. Quatrième volume. Septième Partie. (Paris: Bechet, 1820). vol. 4, pp. 238-74.
Benjamin Constant, Commentaire sur l’ouvrage de Filangieri (Paris: P. Dufart, 1822-24). 2 vols.
Constant, Benjamin, Commentaire sur l’ouvrage de Filangieri (Paris, Les Belles Lettres, 2004). (1822–1824).
Benjamin Constant, Commentary on Filangieri’s Work. Translated, Edited, and with an Introduction by Alan S. Kahan (Indianapolis: Liberty Fund, 2015).
Constant, "De M. Dunoyer et de quelques-un de ses ouvrages" (1829) in in Mélanges de littérature et de politique (1829), pp. 128-62. Mélanges de littérature et de politique (Paris: Pichon et Didier, 1829), pp. 128-62.
Benjamin Constant, On Religion: Considered in Its Source, Its Forms, and Its Developments. Translated by Peter Paul Seaton Jr. with an Introduction by Pierre Manent (Indianapolis: Liberty Fund, 2018).
Charles Coquelin, Des banques au France (Paris: Guillaumin, 1840).
Charles Coquelin, Du Crédit et des Banques (Paris: Guillaumin, 1848).
Coquelin, Du Crédit et des Banques. 2e Édition, revue, annotée, augmentée d'une Introduction par J.-G. Courcelle-Seneuil. Et une Notice Biographique par M. G. de Molinari (Paris: Guillaumin, 1859; 1st edition Guillaumin 1848).
Coquelin and Guillaumin eds. Dictionnaire de l’Économie Politique, contenant l’expostion des principes de la science, l’opinion des écrivains qui ont le plus contribué à sa fondation et à ses progrès, la Bibliographie générale de l’économie politique par noms d’auteurs et par ordre de matières, avec des notices biographiques et une appréciation raisonnée des principaux ouvrages, publié sur la direction de MM. Charles Coquelin et Guillaumin (Paris: Librairie de Guillaumin et Cie, 1852-1853), 2 vols. 2nd ed., 1854; 3rd ed., 1864; 4th ed., 1873.
J.-G. Courcelle-Seneuil, Traité théorique et pratique des opérations de banque, (Paris: Guillaumin, 1853).
J.-G. Courcelle-Seneuil, La Banque libre, exposé des fonctions du commerce de banque et de son application à l"agriculture, suivi de divers écrits de controverse sur la liberté des banques (Paris: Guillaumin, 1867).
Alphonse Courtois, "Le budget de 1848" in the Annuaire de l"économie politique et de la statistique pour 1848. 5e Année (Guillaumin, 1848), pp. 29-51.
Alphonse Courtois, "Le budget de 1849" in Annuaire de l"économie politique et de la statistique pour 1850 par MM. Joseph Garnier. 7e année (Paris: Guillaumin, 1850), pp. 18-28.
Eugène Daire ed. Collection des principaux économistes (Paris: Guillaumin, 1840-48), 15 vols. Avec Commentaires, Notes, et Notices; par MM. Blanqui et Rossi (de l"Institut), Eugène Daire, H. Dussard, J. Garnier, M. Monjean, H. Say. (Paris: Guillaumin, 1840-48).
Daire, "Notice historique sur la vie et les travaux de Boisguillebert", in CPE T. I. Économistes financiers du XVIIIe siècle (1843), pp. 151-61.
Destutt de Tracy, Eléments d'idéologie (Paris: Mme. Levi, 1825-) 5 vols. (1803-1815, 1817–1818).
Destutt de Tracy, *Eléments d'idéologie. IVe et Ve parties. Traité de la volonté et de ses effets(Paris: V. Courcier, 1815).
Destutt de Tracy, Antoine. Commentaire sur l’esprit des lois de Montesquieu; suivi d’observations inédites de Condorcet sur le vingt-neuvième livre du même ouvrage. Édition entièrement conforme à celle publiée à Liége en 1817 (Paris: Delaunay, 1819).
Antoine Louis Claude, Comte Destutt de Tracy, A Treatise on Political Economy: to which is Prefixed a Supplement to a Preceding Work on the Understanding or Elements of Ideology; with an Analytical Table, and an Introduction on the Faculty of the Will (Georgetown: Joseph Milligan, 1817).
Antoine Louis Claude, Comte Destutt de Tracy, A Treatise on Political Economy. Translated by Thomas Jefferson. Edited and with an Introduction by Jeremy Jennings (Indianapolis: Liberty Fund, 2011).
Antoine Louis Claude, Comte Destutt de Tracy, Traité d’économie politique (Paris: Bouguet et Lévi, 1823). Vol. 4 of Eléments d'idéologie reprinted as a stand alone volume with a new title.
Dunoyer, Charles, Oeuvres de Dunoyer, revues sur les manuscrits de l"auteur, 3 vols., ed. Anatole Dunoyer (Paris: Guillaumin, 1870, 1885, 1886).
Dunoyer, Oeuvres de Charles Dunoyer: revues sur les manuscrits de l"auteur. Tome troisième: Notices d'économie sociale. Ed. Anatole Dunoyer (Paris: Guillaumin et Cie., 1886).
Articles by Charles Dunoyer in Le Censeur européen:
Charles Dunoyer, L’Industrie et la morale considérées dans leurs rapport avec la liberté. (Paris: A. Sautelet, 1825).
Dunoyer, Charles, “Esquisse des doctrines auxquelles on a donné le nom d’industrialisme, c’est-à-dire, des doctrines qui fondent la société sur l’industrie”, Revue encyclopédique, XXXIII, 1827, p. 368–394. Reprinted in Oeuvres de Dunoyer, vol. 3, pp. 173-99.
Dunoyer, Charles, review of Jean-Baptiste Say, “Traité d’économie politique” (5th ed.), Revue encyclopédique, XXXIV, 1827, p. 63–90. Reprinted in Oeuvres de Dunoyer, vol. 3, pp. 200-27.
Dunoyer, Charles, review of J.-C.-L. Simonde de Sismondi, “Nouveaux principes d’économie politique”, Revue encyclopédique, XXXIV, 1827, p. 602–622.
Charles Dunoyer, Nouveau traité d'économie sociale, ou simple exposition des causes sous l"influence desquelles les hommes parviennent à user de leurs forces avec le plus de LIBERTÉ, c"est-à-dire avec le plus FACILITÉ et de PUISSANCE (Paris: Sautelet et Mesnier, 1830), 2 vols.
Charles Dunoyer, "Influence du régime prohibitif sur les relations sociales et sur le développement des diverses industries", Journal des économistes, volume 6, 1843, p. 113–138.
Dunoyer, Charles, “Examen de quelques reproches adressées aux tendances industrielles de notre temps”, Séances des travaux de l’Académie des sciences morales et politiques, v. 3, 1843, p. 440–456.
Charles Dunoyer, De la liberté du travail, ou simple exposé des conditions dans lesquelles les force humaines s’exercent avec le plus de puissance. 3 vols. (Paris: Guillaumin, 1845).
Charles Dunoyer, "De l"agitation anglaise pour la liberté commerciale", Journal des économistes, volume 12, 1845, p. 1–24.
Dunoyer, Charles, La Révolution du 24 février (Paris, Guillaumin, 1849).
Dunoyer, Charles, "Des limites de l"économie politique et des fonctions du gouvernement," Journal des économistes, Sept-Dec 1852.
Dunoyer, Charles, “Gouvernement”, in Dictionnaire de l’économie politique (1852), vol. 1, p. 835–841.
Charles Dupin, Le petit producteur français, in 7 vols. Volume 4: “Le petit commerçant français” (Paris: Bachelier, 1827).
Prosper Duvergier de Hauranne, Discours sur les céréales (impr. de P. Dupont, 1832).
Ferdinand-Charles-Philippe d'Esterno, De la Misère, de ses causes, de ses remèdes (Paris: Guillaumin, 1842).
Léon Faucher, Études sur l"Angleterre (Paris: Guillaumin, 1845, 2nd ed. 1856), 2 vols.
Léon Faucher, Du droit au travail (Paris: Guillaumin, 1848).
Léon Faucher, Du système de M. Louis Blanc ou le travail, l"association et l’impôt (Paris: Gerdès, 1848).
Ferrier, François Louis Auguste, Du gouvernement considéré dans ses rapports avec le commerce: Ou, De l"administration commerciale opposée à l"économie politique (Paris: Pélicier, 1821). First edition 1805.
Théodore Fix, ed. Revue mensuelle d'économie politique (Paris: Renard, 1833-36).
Théodore Fix, Observations sur l"état des classes ouvrières (Paris: Guillaumin, 1846).
Henri Fonfrède, Du système prohibitif (Paris: Guillaumin, 1846).
Henri Fonfrède, Oeuvres de Henri Fonfrède, recueillies et mises en ordre par Ch.-Al. Campa, son collaborateur (Paris: Ledoyen, 1846).
Roger de Fontenay, Du revenu foncier (Paris: Guillaumin, 1854).
Fontenay, "Notice sur la vie et les écrits de Frédéric Bastiat," in OC (1862), vol. 1, pp. ix-lii.
Alcide Fonteyraud, "La ligue anglaise" in Revue britannique (Jan. 1846). Reprinted in Fonteyraud, Mélanges d'économie politique. Mis en ordre et augmentés d'une Notice sur l"auteur, ed, Joseph Garnier (Paris: Guillaumin, 1853).
Alcide Fonteyraud, , "Le droit au travail à l’Assemblée nationale, collection de tous les discours et de divers autres écrits, avec une introduction par M. Jos. Garnier," JDE, T. 22, n° 95, 15 février 1849, pp. 333-38.
Fonteyraud, Mélanges d’économie politique. La Ligue anglaise pour la liberté du commerce. Notice historique sur la vie et les travaux de Ricardo. Edited by J. Garnier. Paris: Guillaumin, 1853.
Henri Alcide Fonteyraud and Louis Wolowski No. 92, “Principes d’économie politique,” in Instruction pour le People: Cents traités sur les connaissance les plus indispensables; ouvrage entièrement neuf, avec des gravures intercalées dans le text. Tome second. Traités 51 à 100. (Paris: Paulin et Lechevalier, 1850), pp., 2913-3976.
Charles Fourier, Le Nouveau monde industriel et sociétaire, ou Invention du procédé d'industrie attrayante et naturelle distribuée en séries passionnées (Paris: Bossange père, 1829-1830).
Garnier, Joseph. Introduction à l"étude de l"économie politique, avec des considérations sur la statistique, la liberté du commerce et l"organisation du travail. Ouverture du cours d'économie politique à l"Athénée, le 4 janvier 1843 (Paris: Guillaumin, 1843).
Guillaumin and Joseph Garnier, eds. Annuaire de l’économie politique et de la statistique, 56 vols. (Paris: Guillaumin, 1844-1899).
Guillaumin and Joseph Garnier, eds. Annuaire de l"économie politique et de la statistique, par MM. Guillaumin, Joseph Garnier, Mce Block. Table générale alphabétique et analytique des matières contenues dans les vingt-quatre volumes parus de 1844 à 1867 (Paris: Guillaumin, 1867).
Garnier's notes to CPE 1845 edition of Malthus, Essai sur le principe de population (Paris: Guillaumin, 1845).
Garnier, Joseph, Traité d’économie politique, sociale ou industrielle. Exposé didactique des principes et des applications de cette science avec des développements sur le crédit, les banques, le libre-échange, la protection, l’association, le salaire, etc. (Paris, Garnier/Guillaumin, 1873). (1st ed. 1845).
Joseph Garnier, Éléments de l’Économie politique exposé des notions fondamentales de cette science (Paris: Guillaumin, 1846). 1848, 3rd revised edition Guillaumin 1856.
Joseph Garnier, Richard Cobden, les ligueurs et la ligue, précis de l"histoire de la dernière révolution économique et financière en Angleterre (Paris: Guillaumin, 1846).
Joseph Garnier, Sur l"association, l"économie politique et la misère, position du problème de la misère, ou Considérations sur les moyens généraux d'élever les classes pauvres à une meilleure condition matérielle et morale (Paris: Guillaumin, 1846).
Garnier, Joseph. (ed.), Le droit au travail à l"Assemblée nationale. Recueil complet de tous les discours prononcés dans cette mémorable discussion par MM. Fresneau, Hubert Delisle, Cazalès, Gaulthier de Rumiily, Pelletier, A. de Tocqueville, Ledru-Rolin, Duvergier de Hauranne, Crémieux, M. Barthe, Gaslonde, de Luppé, Arnaud (de l"Ariège), Thiers, Considerant, Bouhier de l"Ecluse, Martin-Bernard, Billault, Dufaure, Goudchaux, et Lagrange (texts revue par les orateurs), suivis de l"opinion de MM. Marrast, Proudhon, Blanc, Louis. Ed. Laboulaye et Cormenin; avec des observations inédites par MM. Faucher, Léon. Wolowski, Fréd. Bastiat, de Parieu, et une introduction et des notes par M. Joseph Garnier (Paris : Guillaumin, 1848).
Garnier, Joseph. Congrès des amis de la paix universelle Réuni à Paris en 1849. Compte-rendu, séances des 22, 23, 24 Aout; - Résolutions adoptées; discours de Mm. Victor Hugo, Visschers, Rév. John Burnett; Rév. Asa Mahan, de l"Ohio; Henri Vincent, de Londres; Ath. Coquerel; Suringar, d'Amsterdam; Francisque Bouvet, Émile de Girardin; Ewart, membre du Parlement; Frédéric Bastiat; Richard Cobden, Elihu Burritt, Deguerry; Amasa Walker, de Massachussets; Ch. Hindley, membre du Parlement, etc., etc.; Compte-rendu d'une visite au Président de la République, de trois meetings en Angleterre; statistique des membres du congrès, etc.; Précédé d'une Note historique sur le mouvement en faveur de la paix, par M. Joseph Garnier. (Paris: Guillaumin, 1850).
Joseph Garnier, “Malthus,” DEP (1853), vol. 2, pp. 126-29.
Joseph Garnier, “Population,” DEP (1853), vol. 2, pp. 382-402.
Garnier (ed.). Malthus, Du principe de population (Paris: Guillaumin, 1857).
Joseph Garnier, “Guillaumin. Ses funérailes, - sa vie et son oeuvre.” JDE. Sér. 2. T.45 (Jan-Mars 1865). No. 133. Jan. 1865, pp. 108-21.
Charles Gide, Principes d'économie politique (Paris: L. Larose et Forcel, 1884).
Charles Gide, Principles of Political Economy. Translated by Edward Percy Jacobsen. With an Introduction and Notes by James Bonar (Boston: D.C. Heath & Co., 1891).
François Eugène Gabriel duc d'Harcourt, Discours en faveur de la liberté du commerce, prononcés à la Chambre des Pairs et à la Chambre des Députés, dans les séances des 10 juin 1835, 21 mai 1845 et 12 janvier 1846 (Paris: Guillaumin, 1846).
Prosper Duvergier de Hauranne, Discours sur les céréales (impr. de P. Dupont, 1832).
Journal des économistes, (1841-). Editors: Gilbert-Urbain Guillaumin (December 1841), Adolphe Blanqui (1842-43), Hippolyte Dussard (1843-45), Joseph Garnier (1845-55).
. Part 1 in “Chronique,” JDE, T. 24, no. 103, Oct. 1849, pp. 315-16; Part 2 in “Chronique,” JDE, 15 Jan. 1850, T. XXV, pp. 202-205; and Part 3 in “Chronique,” JDE, T. XXV, no. 107, 15 fev., 1850, pp. 202-5.
Alphonse de Lamartine, Discours de M. de Lamartine, dans l’Assemblée marseillaise du Libre échange, le 24 août 1847 (Lyon: Léon Boitel, 1847).
Félicité de La Mennais, Essai sur l"indifférence en matière de religion. 4e Edit. (Paris: Tournachon-Molin et Seguin, 1818-20, 1823). 4 vol.
Jules Lebastier, Défense du travail national, ou nécessité de la protection commerciale démontrée à l’aide des principes, des fait et des calculs (Paris: Capelle, 1846).
Thémistocle Lestisboudois, Économie pratique des nations, ou système économique applicable aux différentes contrées, et spécialement à la France (Paris: Colas, 1847). 4 vols.
Alfred Marshall, Principles of Economics (London: Macmillan, 1890).
Marx, The Economic and Philosophical Manuscripts (1844), in Karl Marx, Early writings. Introduced by Lucio Colletti, translated by Rodney Livingstone and Gregor Benton. (Harmondsworth; New York: Penguin in association with New Left Review, 1992).
Karl Marx Frederick Engels Collected Works, vol. 6. Marx Engels 1845-48 (London: Lawrence & Wishart, 2010).
Karl Marx and Friedrich Engels, The Communist Manifesto: A Modern Edition, with an introduction by Eric Hobsbawm. (London : Verso, 2012).
Marx and Engels, Manifest der Kommunistischen Partei. Veröffentlicht im Februar 1848. (London. Gedruckt in der Office der "Bildungs-Gesellschaft für Arbeiter" von J. E. Burghard. 46 Liverpool Street, Bishopsgate ).
J.R. McCulloch, A Dictionary, Practical, Theoretical and Historical of Commerce and Commercial Navigation. Illustrated with maps (London: Printed for Longman, Rees, Orme, Brown, Green, & Longman, 1832).
Mignet, François-Auguste, Nouveaux éloges historiques (Paris, Didier, 1877).
Molinari, Études économiques. L"Organisation de la liberté industrielle et l"abolition de l"esclavage (Paris: Capelle, 1846).
Molinari, “Le droit électorale,” Courrier français, 23 juillet 1846. Reprinted in Questions d'économie politique et de droit public (1861), vol. 2, pp. 271-73.
Gustave de Molinari, Histoire du tarif (Paris: Guillaumin et cie, 1847). Vol. 1: Les fers et les houilles; vol. 2: Les céréales.
Molinari, “Introduction à la huitième année,” JDE, December 1848, T. 28, pp. 1-6.
Gustave de Molinari, "De la production de la sécurité,” Journal des Économistes, T. 22, no. 95, 15 February 1849, pp. 277-90.
Gustave de Molinari, The Production of Security. Trans. J. Huston McCulloch. (New York: Center for Libertarian Studies, 1977).
Gustave de Molinari, Les Soirées de la rue Saint-Lazare; entretiens sur les lois économiques et défense de la propriété (Paris: Guillaumin, 1849).
Molinari, Evenings on Saint-Lazarus Street: Discussions on Economic Laws and the Defence of Property. Edited and with an Introduction by David M. Hart (Liberty Fund, forthcoming).
Molinari, “Le Congrès de la paix, à Paris. — Résolutions du Congrès. — Discours de MM. Victor Hugo, Cobden, Henry Vincent, etc. — Compte-rendu par M. M (Molinari),” JDE, T. 24, N° 102, 15 septembre 1849, pp. 152-73.
Molinari, “ Charles Coquelin,” JDE, N(os) 137 et 138. Septembre et Octobre 1852, pp. 167-76. See p. 172.
Molinari, (1852-53) "Céréales," DEP, T. 1, pp. 301-26; “Liberté des échanges (Associations pour la)” DEP, vol. 2, p. 45-49; Liberté du commerce, liberté des échanges, T. 2, pp. 49-63; Tarifs de douane, T. 2, pp. 712-16; and “Union douanière” (Customs Union), DEP, vol. 2, p. 788-89.
Molinari, Gustave de, “Charles Dunoyer”, in Dictionnaire de l’économie politique (1852), volume 1, Paris, Guillaumin, p. 446–447.
Molinari, Les Révolutions et le despotisme envisagés au point de vue des intérêts matériels; précédé d'une lettre à M. le Comte J. Arrivabene, sur les dangers de la situation présente, par M. G. de Molinari, professeur d'économie politique (Brussels: Meline, Cans et Cie, 1852).
Molinari's review of the DEP: "Dictionnaire de l’économie politique, par M. G. de Molinari," JDE, T. 37, N° 152. 15 Décembre 1853, pp. 420-32.
Molinari, Conservations familières sur le commerce des grains (Paris: Guillaumin, 1855).
Gustave de Molinari, Cours d'économie politique, professé au Musée royal de l"industrie belge, 2 vols. (Bruxelles: Librairie polytechnique d'Aug. Decq, 1855). 2nd ed. 1863.
Molinari, Napoleon III publiciste; sa pensée cherchée dans ses écrits; analyse et appréciation de ses oeuvres (Bruxelles: A. Lacroix, Van Meenen, 1861).
Gustave de Molinari, Questions d'économie politique et de droit public (Paris: Guillaumin; Brussels: Lacroix, 1861), 2 vols.
Molinari, Obituary of Joseph Garnier, JDE, Sér. 4, T. 16, No. 46, October 1881, pp. 5-13.
Molinari, Conversations sur le commerce des grains et la protection de l’agriculture (Paris: Guillaumin, 1886).
Molinari, Gustave de. L"évolution politique et la Révolution (Paris: C. Reinwald, 1884).
Charles Forbes de Montalembert, Du devoir des catholiques dans la question de la liberté d'enseignement (Paris: l"Univers, 1843).
Passy, De l"Instruction secondaire en France, de ses défauts, de leurs causes, et des moyens d'y remédier (Paris: Guillaumin, 1846).
Passy, Frédéric. Notice biographique sur Frédéric Bastiat (Paris: Guillaumin, 1857).
Passy, Frédéric. Mélanges économiques (Paris: Guillaumin, 1857).
Passy, De l"Enseignement obligatoire, discussion entre M. G. de Molinari et M. Frédéric Passy (Paris: Guillaumin, 1859).
Passy, Frédéric. De la propriété intellectuelle, avec V. Modeste et P. Paillottet (Paris: Guillaumin, 1859).
Frédéric Passy, "L"École de la Liberté" in Quatre écoles d'économie sociale. Conférences données à l"aula de l"Université de Genève sous les auspices de la Société chrétienne suisse d'économie sociale. L"École Le Play (Claudio Jannet), L"École collectiviste (G. Stiegler), L"École nouvelle (Charles Gide), L"École de la Liberté (Frédéric Passy). (Genève: Librairie Stapelmohr, éditeur, 1890), pp. 157-231.
J.-P. Proudhon, Qu"est-ce que la propriété? ou Recherches sur le principe du Droit et du Gouvernement. Premier mémoire (Paris: J.-F. Brocard, 1840).
J.-P. Proudhon, Système des contradictions économiques, ou Philosophie de la misère, 2 Volumes (Paris: Guillaumin et cie, 1846).
Pierre-Joseph Proudhon, Banque du peuple: suivie du Rapport de la Commission des délégués du Luxembourg (Paris: Garnier, 1849).
Proudhon and Bastiat. Gratuité du crédit. Discussion entre M. Fr. Bastiat et M. Proudhon (Paris: Guillaumin, 1850).
Antoine-Marie Roederer, Les douanes et l’industrie en 1848: dangers et nécessités, moyens (Paris: Didot, 1847).
Rossi, Cours d'économie politique, année scolaire 1835-1836, semestre d'été (Paris: Ebrard, 1836).
Rossi, Cours d'économie politique, professé au Collège de France (Paris: Guillaumin, 1854).
Rossi, Mélanges d’économie politique, d’histoire et de philosophie, 2 vols. (Paris: Guillaumin, 1857).
Saint-Chamans, Du système d'impôt fondé sur les principes de l"économie politique (Paris: Le Normant, 1820).
Auguste de Saint-Chamans, Nouvel essai sur la richesse des nations (Paris: Le Normant père, 1824). 1st ed. 1821.
Auguste de Saint-Chamans, Traité d’économie publique, suivi d’un aperçu sur les finances de France (1st ed.: Paris: Le Normant père, 1824). And (Paris: Dentu et Ledoyen, 1852).
Saint-Simon, Du système industriel (Paris, chez Antoine-Augustin Renouard, 1821).
Saint-Simon, Henri, Catéchisme des industriels (Paris, Sétier, 1823).
Say, Œuvres complètes. Edited by André Tiran et al. (Paris: Economica, 2002-).
Jean-Baptiste Say, Traité d’économie politique, or simple exposition de la manière dont se forme, se distribuent, et se consomment les richesses. Par Jean-Baptiste Say, Membre de Tribunat (Paris: Crapelet, An XI - 1803). 2 vols. The 2nd revised edition 1814 also contains an "Épitome des principes fondamentaux de l"Économie politique," vol. 2, pp. 421-79. 3rd ed. 1817. 4th revised edition 1819. 5th edition 1826. 6th revised edition 1841.
Jean Baptiste Say, A treatise on political economy; or, The production, distribution, and consumption of wealth. Translated from the fourth edition of the French by C.R. Prinsep, with notes by the translator (London: Longman, Hurst, Rees, Orme, and Brown, 1821). 1st English edition.
Jean Baptiste Say, A treatise on political economy; or The production, distribution, and consumption of wealth. Translated from the 4th ed. of the French by C.R. Prinsep. To which is added, a translation of the introduction and additional notes, by Clement C. Biddle (Boston: Wells and Lilly, 1821). 1st American edition.
Jean-Baptiste Say, Catéchisme d’économie politique, ou Instruction familière qui montre de quelle façon les richesses sont produites, distribuées et consommées dans la société (Paris : impr. de Crapelet, 1815).
Say, Catechism of political economy: or, Familiar conversations on the manner in which wealth is produced, distributed, and consumed in society, trans. John Richter (London: Sherwood, Neely, and Jones, 1816).
Jean Baptiste Say, Petit volume contenant quelques apperçus des hommes et de la société (Paris: Deterville, 1817).
Say, Jean-Baptiste. Leçons d’économie politique, vol. 4 of Œuvres complètes. Ed. Gilles Jacoud and Philippe Steiner (Paris: Économica, 2003), pp. 51-262.
Jean-Baptiste Say, Cours complet d'économie politique pratique. Ouvrage destiné à mettre sous les yeux des hommes d'état, des propriétaires fonciers et les capitalistes, des savans, des agriculteurs, des manufacturiers, des négocians, et en général de tous les citoyens, l"économie des sociétés (Paris: Rapilly, 1828-29). 1828, vols. 1-3; 1829, vols. 4-6. 1833 supplementary volume 7: Mélanges et correspondance d'économie politique; ouvrage posthume de Jean-Baptiste Say; publié par Charles Comte, son gendre. 6 vol. Brussels ed. 1832.
Say, Jean-Baptiste, Cours d’économie politique et autres essais Ed. Philippe Steiner (Paris, Flammarion, 1996).
Say, Cours complet d'économie politique pratique. Éditées par Emmanuel Blanc, Pierre-Henri Goutte, Gilles Jacoud; et André Tiran, coordinateur. Éd. variorum des deux éd. (1828-1840) (Paris : Économica, 2010).
Say, Jean-Baptiste. Politique pratique in Œuvres complètes, vol. 5 : Œuvres morales et politiques, ed. Emmanuel Blanc and André Tiran (Paris : Economica, 2003), pp. 287-822.
Léon Say and Joseph Chailley, eds. Nouveau Dictionnaire d’Économie Politique, publié sous la direction de M. Léon Say et de M. Joseph Chailley. Deuxième édition (Paris: Librairie de Guillaumin et Cie, 1900), 2 vols. .
Sismondi, Jean Charles Léonard Simonde de. De la richesse commerciale, ou principes d'économie politique, appliquées à la législation du commerce (Geneva: J.J. Paschoud, 1803), 2 vols.
Sismondi, Jean Charles Léonard Simonde de. Nouveaux principes d'économie politique, ou de la richesse dans ses rapports avec la population (Paris: Delaunay, 1819), 2 vols.
Sismondi, Jean Charles Léonard Simonde de. Études sur l"économie politique (Paris: Treuttel et Wûrtz, 1837-8), 2 vols.
Stendhal, Le Rouge et le Noir. Chronique du XIXe siècle (1830) (Paris: Éditions Garnier, 1973). Translated as Scarlet and Black. A Chronicle of the Nineteenth Century. Translated and with an introduction by Margaret R. B. Shaw (Harmondsworth: Penguin, 1977).
Stendhal, Lucien Leuwen (1834) Préface de Claude Roy. (Paris: Gallimard, 1960).
Stendhal, D"un nouveau complot contre les industriels, ed. P. Chartier et el. (Paris: Flammarion, 1972).
H. Storch, Cours d’économie politique 1st edition 1815 (St.-Pétersbourg: A. Pluchart et cie., 1815).
Henri Storch, Cours d'économie politique; ou, Exposition des principes qui déterminent la prospérité des nations. Avec des notes explicatives et critiques par J.-B. Say (Paris: J. P. Aillaud, 1823). 4 vols.
Saint-Simon and Augustin Thierry, L"industrie ou Discussions politiques, morales et philosophiques dans l"intérêt de tous les hommes livrés à des travaux utiles et indépendans (Paris: au bureau de l"administration, 1817).
Thierry articles in Le Censeur européen:
Thierry, Augustin. Histoire de la conquête de l’Angleterre par les Normands (Paris: Firmin Didot, 1825). 2 vols.
Thierry, Augustin. History of the Conquest of England by the Normans (London: Whittaker, 1841).
Thierry, Augustin. Essai sur l’histoire de la formation et des progrès du Tiers État suivi de deux fragments du recueil des monuments inédits de cette histoire (Paris: Furne et Ce, 1853).
Thierry, Augustin. The Formation and Progress of the Tiers Etat, or Third Estate in France. Translated from the French, by the Rev. Francis B. Wells (London: T. Bosworth, 1855).
Thierry, Augustin. Dix ans d’études historiques (Paris : J. Tessier, 1835).
Thierry, Augustin. Lettres sur l’histoire de France pour servir d’introduction à l’étude de cette histoire (Paris: Sautelet, 1827).
Thiers, Adolphe. De la propriété (Paris: Paulin, Lheureux et Cie, 1848).
Thomas Perronet Thompson, Contre-enquête par l’homme aux quarante écus (Paris: Charpentier, 1834).
Alexis de Tocqueville, "Mémoire sur le paupérisme" in Mémoires de la Société royale académique de Cherbourg (Cherbourg: Boulanger, Beaufort, et Compagnie, 1835).
Alexis de Tocqueville, "Discours de M. de Tocqueville," in Garnier, Le droit au travail à l"Assemblée nationale (1848), pp. 99-113.
Alban de Villeneuve-Bargemont, Économie politique chrétienne, ou Recherches sur la nature et les causes du paupérisme en France et en Europe, et sur les moyens de le soulager et de le prévenir (Paris: Paulin, 1834). 3 vols.
Wolowski, Louis. Cours de législation industrielle. 6e année. 1re leçon, 27 novembre 1844. De l"organisation du travail (Paris: au bureau de la "Revue de législation et de jurisprudence", 1844).
Wolowski, Louis. Études d'économie politique et de statistique (Paris: Guillaumin, 1848).
Wolowski, Louis and Alcide Fonteyraud, No. 92, “Principes d’économie politique,” in Instruction pour le People: Cents traités sur les connaissance les plus indispensables; ouvrage entièrement neuf, avec des gravures intercalées dans le text. Tome second. Traités 51 à 100. (Paris: Paulin et Lechevalier, 1850), pp. 2913-3976.
The Academy of Moral and Political Sciences website http://www.asmp.fr/sommaire.htm.
René Adenot, Les Idées Économiques et Politiques de Charles Dunoyer. Thèse pour le doctorat en droit (Toulouse: Ch. Marques, 1907).
Florin Aftalion, "Introduction," Frédéric Bastiat, Oeuvres économiques, textes présentés par Florin Aftalion (Paris: Presses Universitaires de France, Collection Libre Echange, 1983), pp. 7-24.
Alain Alcouffe, "The Institutionalization of Political Economy in French Universities: 1819-1896," History of Political Economy, Summer 1989, vol. 21, no. 2, pp. 313-44.
Anon., "Dunoyer," Dictionnaire de l"économie politique (1852), vol. 1, pp. 622-3.
“Beacon for Freedom of Expression” database of banned books with the entry for the DEP http://search.beaconforfreedom.org/search/censored_publications/publication.html?id=9709582.
Alain Béraud and Philippe Steiner, “France, economics in (before 1870)”, vol. 3, pp. 475-80 and “France, economics in (after 1870)”, vol. 3, pp. 481-86, in The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. Second Edition. Edited by Steven N. Durlauf and Lawrence E. Blume (Houndmills, Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, 2008).
Breton, Yves. “The Société d’économie politique of Paris (1842–1914)” in The Spread of Political Economy and the Professionalisation of Economists: Economic Societies in Europe, America and Japan in the Nineteenth Century, edited by Massimo M. Augello and Marco E. L. Guidi. (London: Routledge, 2001), pp. 53-69.
Yves Breton et Michel Lutfalla (eds.), L"économie politique en France au XIXème siècle, (Paris: Economica, 1991).
Gilbert Faccarello, “Bold ideas. French liberal economists and the State: Say to Leroy-Beaulieu,” in The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 17 (4), 2010, pp. 719–758.
Amable Charles comte de Franqueville, Le premier siècle de l"Institut de France, 25 octobre, 1795-25 octobre, 1895: Notices sur les membres libres, les associés étrangers et les correspondants. Fondations et prix décernés. Personnel des anciennes académies. Two vols. (Paris: J. Rothschild, 1896).
Pierre Garello (ed.), Journal des Économistes et des Études Humaines, vol. 11, no. 2/3 (Jun 2001). Editor-in-Chief: Garello, Pierre. Special issue devoted to papers given at the Bastiat bicentennial conference. Online http://www.degruyter.com/view/j/jeeh.2001.11.2/issue-files/jeeh.2001.11.issue-2.xml.
Raf Geneens and Helena Rosenblatt eds. French Liberalism from Montesquieu to the Present Day (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2012).
Jacques de Guenin, Logique du libéralisme: morale, vie en société, économie (Paris: Institut Charles Coquelin, 2006).
Bastiat, La loi; suivi de Spoliation et loi. Introduction de Jacques de Guenin (Mont-de-Marsan: J. Lacoste, 1991).
Hamowy, ed. The Encyclopedia of Libertarianism, ed. Ronald Hamowy (Los Angeles: Sage, 2008. A Project of the Cato Institute). See the entries for “Jean-Baptiste Say”; "Destutt de Tracy"; “Benjamin Constant”; “Charles Comte”; “Charles Dunoyer”; “Frédéric Bastiat”; “Gustave de Molinari”; "Tocqueville, Alexis de (1805-1859)."
Éphraïm Harpaz, Le Censeur. Le Censeur européen. Histoire d'un Journal libéral et industrialiste (Genève: Slatkine Reprints, 2000).
David M. Hart, "Gustave de Molinari and the Anti-Statist Liberal Tradition," Journal of Libertarian Studies, Vol. 5, no. 3 (Summer 1981), pp. 263-90; Vol. 5, no. 4 (Fall 1981), pp. 399-434; and Vol. 6, No. 4 (Winter 1982), pp. 83-104.
David M. Hart, Class Analysis, Slavery and the Industrialist Theory of History in French Liberal Thought, 1814-1830: The Radical Liberalism of Charles Comte and Charles Dunoyer (unpublished PhD, King's College Cambridge, 1994).
David M. Hart, "Broken Windows and House-Owning Dogs: The French Connection and the Popularization of Economics from Bastiat to Jasay," Symposium on Anthony de Jasay, The Independent Review (Summer 2015), vol. 20, no. 1, pp. 61-84.
David M. Hart, “Negative Railways, Turtle Soup, talking Pencils, and House owning Dogs”: “The French Connection” and the Popularization of Economics from Say to Jasay. (September, 2014). Unpublished manuscript.
David M. Hart, "For Whom the Bell Tolls: The School of Liberty and the Rise of Interventionism in French Political Economy in the Late 19thC" Journal of Markets and Morality, vol. 20, Number 2 (Fall 2017), pp. 383-412.
Hart et al. Social Class and State Power: Exploring an Alternative Radical Tradition, ed. David M. Hart, Gary Chartier, Ross Miller Kenyon, and Roderick T. Long (Palgrave Macmillan, 2018).
David M. Hart, Glossaries and Notes in the Collected Works of Bastiat, vol. 3 (2017).
David M. Hart, Glossaries and Notes in the Collected Works of Bastiat, vol. 4 (forthcoming).
Jörg Guido Hülsmann, “Bastiat’s Legacy in Economics,” The Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, vol. 4, no. 4, (Winter 2001), pp. 55–70.
Anthony de Jasay, "Thirty-five Hours," Library of Economics and Liberty (Econlib), July 15, 2002 http://www.econlib.org/library/Columns/Jasaywork.html.
Les penseurs libéraux, eds. Alain Laurent et Vincent Valentin (Paris: Les Belles Lettres, 2012).
Lepage, Henri, “Redécouvrir les libéraux de la Restauration: Comte et Dunoyer”, in Alain Madelin (dir.), Aux sources du modèle libéral français (Paris, Perrin, 1997), p. 139–154.
Robert Leroux, Lire Bastiat: Science sociale et libéralisme (Paris: Hermann, 2008).
Robert Leroux, Political Economy and Liberalism in France: The Contributions of Frédéric Bastiat (London: Routledge, 2011).
Robert Leroux and David M. Hart, eds. L"âge d`or du libéralisme français. Anthologie. XIXe siècle. Robert Leroux et David M. Hart. Préface de Mathieu Laine (Paris: Editions Ellipses, 2014).
Robert Leroux and David M. Hart, eds. French Liberalism in the 19th Century: An Anthology. Edited by Robert Leroux and David M. Hart (London: Routledge, 2012).
Robert Leroux, *Aux fondements de l"industrialisme: Comte, Dunoyer et la pensée libérale en France (Paris: Hermann, 2015).
Robert Leroux, The Foundations of Industrialism: Charles Comte, Charles Dunoyer and Liberal Thought in France (New York: Peter Lang, 2016).
Leter, "Préface: Frédéric Bastiat et les fondements littéraires de l"analyse économique," Bastiat, Sophismes économiques; préf. de Michel Leter (Paris: les Belles lettres, 2009, 1st ed. 2004), pp. 7-38.
Leter, "Préface," Pamphlets (Paris: les Belles lettres, 2009, 1st ed. 2004), pp. 7-31.
Michel Leter, “Éléments pour une étude de l’École de Paris (1803-1852), in Histoire du libéralisme en Europe, eds. Philippe Nemo and Jean Petitot (Pais: Presses Universitaires de France, 2006), pp. 429-509.
Lucette Le Van-Lemesle, "La promotion de l"économie politique en France au XIXe siècle jusqu"à son introduction dans le facultés (1815-1881)," Revue d'histoire moderne et contemporaine, 27 April 1980, pp. 270-94.
Lucette Levan-Lemesle, “Guillaumin, Éditeur d’Économie politique 1801-1864,” Revue d’économie politique, 96e année, No. 2, 1985, pp. 134-149.
Leonard P. Liggio, Dunoyer and the Bourbon Restoration of 1814–15. (Unpublished draft dissertation, Fordham University in New York City).
Liggio, Leonard P., "Charles Dunoyer and French Classical Liberalism," Journal of Libertarian Studies, 1977, vol. 1, no. 3, pp. 153-78.
Michel Lutfalla, "Aux Origines du liberalisme economique en France: le Journal des Économistes; Analyse du contenu de la premiere serie, 1841-53," Revue d'histoire économique et sociale, no. 4 (1974).
Lutfalla, Michel, “Jean-Baptiste Say, le fondateur”, in Yves Breton and Michel Lutfalla (dir.), L’économie politique en France au XIXe siècle (Paris, Economica, 1991), p. 13–31.
, Aux sources du modèle libéral français, sous la direction de Alain Madelin (Paris: Perrin, 1997).
Benoît Malbranque, "Liste complète des titres publiés par Guillaumin (1837-1910)", Institut Coppet (janvier 2, 2017), https://www.institutcoppet.org/2017/01/02/liste-complete-titres-publies-guillaumin-1837-1910.
Minart, Gérard. Frédéric Bastiat (1801-1850). Le croisé de libre-échange (Paris: L’Harmattan, 2004).
Minart, Gérard. Jean-Baptiste Say (1767-1832). Maître et pédagogue de l’école française d’économie politique libérale (Paris: Institut Charles-Coquelin, 2005).
Minart, Gérard. Gustave de Molinari (1819-1912), pour un gouvernement à bon marché dans un milieu libre (Paris: Institut Charles Coquelin, 2012).
Nataf, Philippe. “La vie et l’oeuvre de Charles Coquelin (1802-1852),” in Histoire du libéralisme en Europe, eds. Philippe Nemo and Jean Petitot (Pais: Presses Universitaires de France, 2006), pp.511-30.
Philippe Nemo et Jean Petitot ed., Histoire de libéralisme en Europe (Paris: Quadrige PUF, 2006).
Patricia O"Brien, “L’Embastillement de Paris: The Fortification of Paris during the July Monarchy,” French Historical Studies, Vol. 9, No. 1 (Spring, 1975), pp. 63-82.
Pénin, Marc, “Charles Dunoyer, l’échec d’un libéralisme”, in Yves Breton and Michel Lutfalla (dir.), L’économie politique en France au XIXe siècle, (Paris, Economica, 1991), p. 33–81.
Poitier, Jean-Pierre and André Tiran, eds. Jean-Baptiste Say: Nouveau regards sur son oeuvre (Paris: Economica, 2003).
"E.R." article "Dunoyer," Nouveau Dictionnaire d’économie politique, ed. Léon Say and Joseph Chailley (Paris: Guillaumin et Cie, 1891), vol. 1, p. 750.
Ralph Raico, The Place of Religion in the Liberal Philosophy of Constant, Tocqueville, and Lord Acton (1970). A Dissertation Submitted to the University of Chicago’s Faculty of the Division of the Social Sciences in Candidacy for the Degree of Doctor of Philosophy for the Committee on Social Thought, Chaired by F. A. Hayek (Auburn, Alabama: Ludwig von Mises Institute, 2010).
Ralph Raico, “The Centrality of French liberalism” in Classical Liberalism and the Austrian School, Foreword by Jörg Guido Hülsmann. Preface by David Gordon (Auburn, Alabama: Ludwig von Mises Institute, 2012), pp. 219–53.
Ravix, Joël, « Le libre-échange et le protectionnisme en France », in Yves Breton and Michel Lutfalla (dir.), L’économie politique en France au XIXe siècle (Paris, Economica, 1991), p. 485–523.
Murray N. Rothbard, Classical Economics: An Austrian Perspective on the History of Economic Thought. Volume II (Auburn, Alabama: Ludwig von Mises Institute, 2006).
Fernand Rudé, Stendhal et la pensée sociale de son temps (New enlarged edition. Brionne: Gérard Monfort, 1983).
Joseph T. Salerno, "The Neglect of Bastiat's School by English-Speaking Economists: A Puzzle Resolved," Journal des économistes et des Etudes Humaines, vol. 11, no. 2/3 (June/September 2001), pp. 451-95.
Larry Siedentop, "The Two Liberal Traditions," The Idea of Freedom: Essays in Honour of Isaiah Berlin, ed. Alan Ryan (Oxford University Press, 1979).
Larry Siedentop, "Two Liberal Traditions," in Raf Geneens and Helena Rosenblatt eds. French Liberalism from Montesquieu to the Present Day (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2012), pp. 15-35.
Smithson, Rulon Nephi, Augustin Thierry. Social and Political Consciousness in the Evolution of Historical Method (Geneva, Droz, 1973).
Spitzer, Alan Barrie, The French Generation of 1820 (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1987).
Martin S. Staum, "French Lecturers in Political Economy, 1815-1848: Varieties of liberalism," History of Political Economy, 1998, 30(1), 95-120.
Todd, David, L’identité économique de la France, Libre-échange et protectionnisme 1814–1851, (Paris: Grasset, 2008).
David Todd, Free Trade and its Enemies in France, 1814–1851 (Cambridge University Press, 2015).
Weinburg, Mark, “The Social Analysis of Three Early 19th Century French Liberals: Say, Comte, and Dunoyer”, Journal of Libertarian Studies, vol. 2, no. 1, 1978, p. 45–63.
Bourdeau, Michel and Béatrice Fink, “De l’industrie à l’industrialisme: Benjamin Constant aux prises avec le Saint-Simonisme. Une étude en deux temps”, Œuvres critiques, XXXIII, I, 2008, p. 61–78.
Breton, Yves, “Michel Chevalier, entre le saint-simonisme et le libéralisme”, in Yves Breton et Michel Lutfalla, Michel, L’économie politique en France au XIXe siècle, Paris, Economica, 1991, p. 247–275.
Craiutu, Aurelian, A Virtue for Courageous Minds. Moderation in French Political Thought, 1748–1830 (Princeton and Oxford, Princeton University Press, 2012).
De Dijn, Annelien, French Political Thought from Montesquieu to Tocqueville. Liberty in a Levelled Society? (Cambridge, Canbridge University Press, 2008).
Fontaine, Philippe, “The Concept of Industrie from the Physiocrats to J.-B. Say”, Contributions to Political Economy, 12, 1993, p. 89–97.
Girard, Louis, Les libéraux français, 1814–1875, Paris, Aubier, 1985.
Jainchill, Andrew, Reimagining Politics after the Terror: the Republican Origins of French Liberalism (Ithaca and London, Cornell University Press, 2008).
Keslassy, Éric, Le libéralisme de Tocqueville à l’épeuvre du paupérisme (Paris, L’Harmattan, 2000).
Manent, Pierre, Histoire intellectuelle du libéralisme (Paris Hachette, 1987).
Pitts, Jennifer, A Turn to Empire. The Rise of Imperial Liberalism in Britain and France (Princeton, Princeton University Press, 2005).
Pitts, Jennifer, “Constant’s Thought on Slavery and Empire”, in Helena Rosenblatt, The Cambridge Companion to Constant (Cambridge, University of Cambridge Press, 2009), p. 115–145.
Rosanvallon, Pierre, Le moment Guizot (Paris, Gallimard, 1985).
Rosenblatt, Helena, “Re-evaluating Benjamin Constant’s liberalism: industrialism, Saint-Simonism and the Restoration years”, History of European Ideas, 30, 2004, p. 23–37.
Rosenblatt, Helena, The Cambridge Companion to Constant (Cambridge, University of Cambridge Press, 2009).
We have used the lists drawn up by Michel Leter with some modifications. We have modified Leter's division of the generations slightly - what he calls "precursors" I prefer to call the first generation. I believe the Physiocrats are the true "precursors" of the Paris School.
Michel Leter, “Éléments pour une étude de l’École de Paris (1803-1852)," in Histoire du libéralisme en Europe, eds. Philippe Nemo and Jean Petitot (Paris: Presses Universitaires de France, 2006), pp. 429-509. His lists are on pp. 448-49.
(Added by DMH)
The first generation were born under the Old Regime and were active during the Empire and the Restoration.
Leter lists a total of 13 people in this generation of which I have selected five of the most important to discuss in the article (in bold). They are (in order of date of birth):
The second generation of the Paris School were born during the French Revolution and the First Empire.
Leter lists 26 people in this generation of which I have selected five of the most important to discuss here. They are (in order of date of birth):
Michel Leter was interested in describing the activities of the Paris School across the entire 19th century and so includes 23 individuals in total as comprising this generation. Only nine of these were old enough to have been active during the late July Monarchy and Second Republic. The full list in chronological order by birth is:
Leter also provides a useful list of those members of the Paris School who held positions in the French government. These were the following:
Boisguilbert was a magistrate and president of the Civil Court in Rouen. In the late 17th century he was struck by the poverty he saw around him and wrote a detailed account of what he saw, Détail de la France (1695), blaming the mercantilist polices of Colbert and King Louis XIV for the people's sufferings. He followed this with another book Dissertation sur la nature des richesses (1707) where he argued that labour which was freed from its shackles and an economy in which there was competition would produce a "natural order" in which both ordinary people and the state could flourish. His books were banned by the state so he went into exile in the Auvergne. His writings would have an significant impact on Quesany and the other Physiocrats later in the 18th century. His major works are Détail de la France (1695), Factum de la France (1707), Dissertation sur la nature des richesses (1707), and Traité des grains (1707).
Richard Cantillon was an Irish-French banker and merchant who was also an early economic theorist writing an Essay on the Nature of Trade in General in about 1730. Cantillon made a fortune in the 1710s and 1720s with speculative deals such as his involvement with John Law's Mississippi Company which went bust in a spectacular way. His personal experiences in banking and international finance lead him to have interesting things to say about money, foreign exchange, banking, and risk, but his most important contribution was the development of a theory of the entrepreneur well before Jean-Baptiste Say. His Essay was not published until 1755 but it did have an influence on Quesnay in France and Smith in Scotland.
François Quesnay (1694-1774) was both a surgeon and an economist. He taught at the Paris School of Surgery and was the personal doctor to Madame Pompadour. As an economist he is best known as one of the founders of the physiocratic school, writing the articles on “Fermiers”and “Grains” for Diderot’s Encylopédie (1756) and also Le Tableau économique (1762) and Physiocratie, ou constitution naturelle de gouvernement le plus avantageux au genre humain (1768). His major works were republished by the Guillaumin firm as vol. 2 of the Collection des principaux économistes (1840-48) edited by Eugène Daire.
The Abbé de Condillac (1714-80) was a priest, philosopher, economist, and member of the Académie française. Condillac was an advocate of the ideas of John Locke and a friend of the encyclopedist Denis Diderot. In his Traité des sensations (1754), Condillac claims that all attributes of the mind, such as judgment, reason, and even will, derive from sensations. His book Le Commerce et le gouvernement, considérés relativement l"un a l"autre (1776) appeared in the same year as Adam Smith’s Wealth of Nations.
Turgot was an economist of the physiocratic school, a politician, a reformist bureaucrat, and a writer. During the mid 1750s Turgot came into contact with the physiocrats, such as Quesnay, Dupont de Nemours, and Vincent de Gournay (who was the free-market intendant for commerce). Turgot had two opportunities to put free-market reforms into practice: when he was appointed Intendant of Limoges in 1761-74; and when Louis XVI made him minister of finance between 1774 and 1776, at which time Turgot issued his six edicts to reduce regulations and taxation. His works include Eloge de Gournay (1759), Réflexions sur la formation et la distribution des richesses (1766), and Lettres sur la liberté du commerce des grains (1770). His works were republished by the Guillaumin firm as vols. 3 and 4 of the Collection des principaux économistes (1840-48) edited by Eugène Daire.
Antoine Destutt de Tracy (1754-1836) was one of the leading intellectuals of the 1790s and early 1800s and a member of the "ideologues" (a philosophical movement not unlike the objectivists, who professed that the origin of ideas was material–not spiritual). In his writings on Montesquieu, Tracy defended the institutions of the American Republic, and in his writings on political economy he defended laissez-faire. During the French Revolution he joined the third estate and renounced his aristocratic title. During the Terror he was arrested and nearly executed. Tracy continued agitating for liberal reforms as a senator during Napoleon’s regime. One of his most influential works was the four-volume Éléments d’idéologie (first published in 1801-15) (Tracy coined the term “ideology”). He also wrote Commentaire sur l"ésprit des lois (1819), which Thomas Jefferson translated and brought to the United States. In 1823 he published his Traité d’économie politique (1823), much admired by Jefferson and Bastiat.
Benjamin Constant (1767-1830) was a novelist, politician, and political theorist during the Napoleonic and Restoration periods. Born in Lausanne, Constant was a close friend of Germaine de Staël and accompanied her to Paris in 1795. He was a supporter of the Directory and a member of the Tribunat but came to oppose the loss of political liberty under Napoleon. He became a staunch opponent of Napoleon, but in spite of this he was approached by him during the “Hundred Days” (period between Napoleon’s return from exile on Elba to Paris on 20 March 1815 and the restoration of King Louis XVIII on 8 July 1815) to draw up a constitution for a more liberal, constitutional empire. Constant became a deputy in 1819 and continued to defend constitutional freedoms until his death. He is best known for his novel Adolphe (1807), Principes de politique applicables à tous les gouvernements (1815), De l’esprit de conquête et de l’usurpation, dans leurs rapports à la civilization européen (1814), and Cours de politique constitutionelle (1820).
Jean-Baptiste Say (1767-1832) was the leading French political economist in the first third of the nineteenth century. Before becoming an academic political economist quite late in life, Say apprenticed in a commercial office, working for a life insurance company; he also worked as a journalist, soldier, politician, cotton manufacturer, and writer. During the revolution he worked on the journal of the idéologues, La Décade philosophique, littéraire, et politique, for which he wrote articles on political economy from 1794 to 1799. In 1814 he was asked by the government to travel to England on a fact-finding mission to discover the secret of English economic growth and to report on the impact of the revolutionary wars on the British economy. His book De l"Angleterre et des Anglais (1815) was the result. After the defeat of Napoleon and the restoration of the Bourbon monarchy, Say was appointed to teach economics in Paris, first at the Athénée, then as a chair in "industrial economics" at the Conservatoire national des arts et métiers, and finally the first chair in political economy at the Collège de France. Say is best known for his Traité d'économie politique (1803), which went through many editions (and revisions) during his lifetime. One of his last major works, the Cours complet d'économie politique pratique (1828-33), was an attempt to broaden the scope of political economy, away from the preoccupation with the production of wealth, by examining the moral, political, and sociological requirements of a free society and how they interrelated with the study of political economy.
Joseph Droz (1773-1850) was a moral philosopher, economist, literary critic, and father-in-law of Michel Chevalier. Some of his notable publications include Lois relatives au progrès de l’industrie (1801); Économie politique, ou, Principes de la science des richesses (1829); and Applications de la morale à la politique (1825). He was appointed to the Académie française in 1813 and to the Académie des sciences morales et politiques in 1833.
Charles Comte (1782-1837) was a lawyer, a critic of the repressive policies of Napoleon and then the restored monarchy, and the son-in-law of the economist Jean-Baptiste Say. He founded, with Charles Dunoyer, the journal Le Censeur in 1814 and Le Censeur européen in 1817 and was prosecuted many times for challenging the press censorship laws and criticizing the government. He came across the economic ideas of Say in 1817 and discussed them at length in Le Censeur européen. After the government passed new censorship laws in 1820, it closed closed down the magazine and convicted and sentenced Comte to two years in prison.
He went into exile in Switzerland, living in Geneva for 15 months, before accepting a position in Lausanne teaching law. Comte believed that the Ultra conservatives in France would put pressure on other countries like Switzerland who gave shelter to liberal exiles and critics of the government. Therefore, he resigned his teaching position after two years in Lausanne and went to England in 1824 where he spent another two years and became acquainted with Jeremy Bentham and other English liberals, including James and John Stuart Mill.
He was able to return to France in 1825 where he worked on Lafayette’s journal La Revue Américaine. In 1827 he published the first part of his magnum opus, the four-volume Traité de législation, which very much influenced the thought of Bastiat, and the second part, Traité de la propriété which followed in 1834. Comte was appointed to the Académie des sciences morales et politiques when it was re-established by King Louis Philippe in 1832, and was its permanent secretary. After the 1830 revolution he was also elected a deputy representing La Sarthe.
Dunoyer was a journalist, an economist, a politician, the author of numerous works on politics, political economy, and history, a founding member and President of the Société d’économie politique (1842) and its President between 1845 and 1862, and a key figure in the French classical liberal movement of the first half of the nineteenth century, along with Jean-Baptiste Say, Benjamin Constant, Charles Comte, Augustin Thierry, and Alexis de Tocqueville. Dunoyer studied law in Paris where he met Charles Comte (around 1807) with whom he was to edit the liberal periodical Le Censeur (1814-15) and its successor Le Censeur européen (1817-19). He became politically active during the last years of Napoleon's Empire and the early years of the Bourbon Restoration when he strenuously opposed authoritarian rule (whether Napoleonic or monarchical), especially censorship of the press, militarism, the slave trade, and the extensive restrictions placed on trade and industry. Dunoyer (and Comte) combined the political liberalism of Constant (constitutional limits on the power of the state, representative government); the economic liberalism of Say (laissez-faire, free trade); and the sociological approach to history of Thierry, Constant, and Say (class analysis and a theory of historical evolution of society through stages culminating in the laissez-faire market society of “industry”) into a new and rich form of classical liberal thought which had a profound impact in France, especially on people like Bastiat.
He is best known for a series of works on industry and labour published between 1825 and 1845, L’Industrie et la morale considérées dans leurs rapports avec la liberté (1825), Nouveau traité d’économie sociale (1830), and his three-volume magnum opus De la liberté du travail (1845). After the revolution of 1830 Dunoyer was appointed a member of the Académie des sciences morales et politiques in 1832, worked as a government official (he was prefect of L’Allier and La Somme), and eventually became a member of the Council of State in 1837. He resigned his government posts in protest against the coup d’état of Louis-Napoléon in 1851. He died while writing a critique of the authoritarian Second Empire; the work was completed and published by his son Anatole in 1864.
François-Eugène-Gabriel, duc d’Harcourt (1786-1865) served briefly in the military in the early years of the Restoration before resigning in order to support the Greek struggle for independence from Turkey. He was elected to represent Seine-et-Marne in 1827 and supported the liberal opposition to Charles X. Under the July Monarchy he was appointed ambassador to Madrid, was active in the reform of secondary education, and was a supporter of free trade. Because of his speeches on behalf of free trade in the Chamber and because of his social and political contacts he was appointed president of the Free Trade Association when it was founded in 1846. During the Second Republic he was appointed ambassador to Rome by Lamartine.
Pellegrino Rossi (1787-1848) was born in Italy and lived in Geneva, Paris, and Rome. He was a professor of law and political economy, wrote poetry, and ended his days as a diplomat for the French government. He moved to Switzerland after the defeat of Napoleon, where he met Germaine de Staël and the duc de Broglie. He founded with Sismondi and Etienne Dumont the Annales de législation et des jurisprudences. After the death of Jean-Baptiste Say, Rossi was appointed professor of political economy at the Collège de France in 1833, and in 1836 he became a member of the Académie des sciences morales et politiques. In 1847 he was appointed ambassador of France to the Vatican but was assassinated on 15 November 1848 in Rome. He wrote Cours d’économie politique (1840), Traité de droit pénal (1841), and numerous articles in the Journal des économistes.
Henri Jean Étienne Boyer-Fonfrède (1788-1841) was a liberal journalist who lived in Bordeaux. He and his uncle started a shipping business in Bordeaux in 1816 before he became interested in liberal politics. He edited the journal La Tribune before founding the Indicateur de Bordeaux (1826) and the Courrier de Bordeaux (1837) in which he promoted his ideas. He published several books on constitutional government and in 1846 the Guillaumin firm published a collection of his writings on free trade. See, Henri Fonfrède, Du gouvernement du roi, et des limites constitutionnelles de la prérogative parlementaire (Paris: H. Delloye, 1839); Du système prohibitif (Paris: Guillaumin, 1846); Oeuvres de Henri Fonfrède, recueillies et mises en ordre par Ch.-Al. Campa, son collaborateur (Paris: Ledoyen, 1846).
Alphonse de Lamartine (1790–1869) was a poet and statesman and as an immensely popular romantic poet, he used his talent to promote liberal ideas. Lamartine was elected Deputy representing Nord (1833-37), Saône et Loire (1837-Feb. 1848), Bouches-du-Rhône (April 1848-May 1849), and Saône et Loire (July 1849- Dec. 1851). During the campaign for free trade organised by the French Free Trade Association between 1846 and 1847 Lamartine often spoke at their large public meetings and was a big draw card. He was a member of the Provisional Government in February 1848 (offering Bastiat a position in the government, which he declined) and Minister of Foreign Affairs in June 1848. After he lost the presidential elections of December 1848 against Louis-Napoléon, he gradually retired from political life and went back to writing.
Hippolyte Philibert Passy (1793-1880) was a cavalry officer in Napoleon’s army and after the restoration of the monarchy took a trip to the United States, during which he discovered the works of Adam Smith. After his return to France he wrote for several opposition papers, such as the liberal National (with Thiers and Mignet), and published a book, De l’aristocracie considérée dans ses rapports avec les progrès de la civilization (1826). Passy was elected as a deputy from 1830, serving as minister of finance in 1834, 1839-40, and 1848-49. In 1838 he became a member of the Académie des sciences morales et politiques, in which he served for some forty years and was particularly active in developing political economy. He criticized the colonization of Algeria and was an advocate of free trade. He was cofounder of the Société d’économie politique (1842) and wrote numerous articles in the Journal des économistes and several books, among which included Des systèmes de culture et de leur influence sur l"économie sociale (1846) and Des causes de l"inégalité des richesses (1848).
Augustin-Charles Renouard (1794-1878) was a lawyer with an interest in elementary school education. He was secretary general of the minister of justice and an elected deputy representing the Somme 1831-1842. He also was vice-president of the Société d’économie politique and wrote or edited a number of works on economic and educational matters. He was particularly interested in the issue of trade marks and intellectual property taking issue with Molinari’s view that an author’s right to intellectual property was absolute and perpetual. Some of his works include a selection of Benjamin Franklin’s writings, Mélanges de morale, d’économie et de politique (1824), Traité des brevets d'invention, de perfectionnement et d'importation (1825), and “L’éducation doit-elle être libre?”in Revue encyclopédique (1828); Traité des droits d'auteurs (1838).
The Say family played a very important role in liberal political economy circles in France for nearly 100 years. It began with Jean-Baptiste Say (1767-1832), then his son Horace Émile Say (1794-1860), and his grandson Léon Say (1826-96).
Horace Say was the son of Jean-Baptiste Say. He married Anne Cheuvreux, sister of Casimir Cheuvreux, whose family were friends of Bastiat. Say was a businessman and traveled in 1813 to the United States and Brazil. A result of his trip was Historie des relations commerciales entre la France et le Brésil (1839). He became president of the Chamber of Commerce of Paris in 1834, became a councillor of state (1849-51), and headed an important inquiry into the state of industry in the Paris region (1848-51). Say was also very active in liberal circles, participating in the foundation of the Société d’économie politique, the Guillaumin publishing firm, the Journal des économistes, the Journal du commerce; and was an important collaborator in the creation of the Dictionnaire de l’économe politique and the Dictionnaire du commerce et des marchandises. In 1857 he was nominated to the Académie des sciences morales et politiques but died before he could join it formally. He also wrote two important works, Paris, son octroi et ses emprunts (1847) which was analysis and critique of the octroi tax on imported goods into the city of Paris, and on behalf of the Chamber of Commerce of Paris a detailed analysis of the state of industry in the city, Statistique de l’Industrie à Paris résultant de l’enquête. Faite par la Chambre de commerce pour les années 1847-1848 (1851).
Jacques-Nicolas Augustin Thierry (1795-1856) was a pioneering historian who is famous for his classical liberal class analysis of history and his extensive use of archival records in researching and writing this history. He began as the personal assistant to Saint-Simon (1814-1817) before joining Charles Comte and Charles Dunoyer on their journal Le Censeur européen. It was here that he learned to analyze history using the social and economic theories developed by Comte and Dunoyer via the work of Jean-Baptiste Say. Thierry became interested in the ruling elites which governed nations, how they came to power (often through conquest as the Normans did of Saxon England), and the gradual emergence of free institutions such as the medieval communes and the Third Estate. He was favoured by Guizot and other political leaders of the July Monarchy who encouraged his archival research with an appointment to the Académie des inscriptions et belles lettres (1830) and the editorship of a massive collection of documents published as Recueil des monuments inédits de l’histoire du Tiers état (1850-1870). His collected writings from Le Censeur européen were later published as Dix ans d’études historiques (1834). His other works include Histoire de la conquête de l’Angleterre par les Normands (1825), Lettres sur l’histoire de France (1827), and Essai sur l’histoire de la formation et des progrès du Tiers état (1850).
Antoine-Elisée Cherbuliez (1797-1869) was a Swiss lawyer, judge, and professor of law and political economy at the Académie de Genève. He was elected to the Cantonal Legislature in 1831 and then to the Constituent Assembly in 1842. In 1848 he moved to Paris and became active in the Economists" circle, writing for the JDE and participating in the pamphlet war of 1848 on socialism. He returned to academic life in Switzerland five years later. His books include Riche ou pauvre exposition succincte des causes et des effets de la distribution actuelle des richesses sociales (1840); De la démocratie en Suisse (1843); Simples Notions de l"ordre social à l"usage de tout le monde (1848); Le potage à la tortue: entretiens populaires sur les questions sociales (1849); Etudes sur les causes de la misère tant morale que physique et sur les moyens d'y porter remède (1853); Précis de la science économique et de ses principales applications (1862).
Eugène Daire (1798-1847) was of all things a tax collector who revived interest in the heritage of eighteenth- and early nineteenth-century free-market economics. He came to Paris in 1839, met Guillaumin, discovered the works of Jean-Baptiste Say, and began editing the fifteen-volume work, Collection des principaux économistes (1840-48). It included works on eighteenth-century finance, the physiocrats, Turgot, Adam Smith, Malthus, Jean-Baptiste Say, and Ricardo. He was a founding member of the Political Economy Society.
Reybaud was a businessman, journalist, novelist, fervent anti-socialist, politician, and writer on economic and social issues. In 1846 he was elected deputy representing Marseilles, but his strong opposition to Napoléon III and the empire forced him to retire to devote himself to political economy. He became a member of the Académie des sciences morales et politiques in 1850. His writings include the prizewinning critique of socialists, Études sur les réformateurs et socialistes modernes: Saint-Simon, Charles Fourier, Robert Owen (1840); the satirical novel Jérôme Paturot à la recherché d’une position sociale (1843); and Économistes contemporains (1861). Reybaud also wrote many articles for Le Journal des économistes and the Dictionnaire de l’économie politique (1852).
Blanqui was a liberal economist; brother of the revolutionary socialist Auguste Blanqui. He became director of the prestigious École supérieure de commerce de Paris, succeeded Jean-Baptiste Say to the chair of political economy at the Conservatoire national des arts et métiers, and was the editor of the Journal des Économistes between 1842 and 1843 and often wrote articles under the nom de plume of “Adolphus”. He was elected deputy representing the Gironde from 1846 to 1848. Among his many works on political economy and sociology are the Encyclopédie du commerçant (1839-41), Précis élementaire d’économie politique (1842), and Les classes ouvrières en France (1848).
Hippolyte Dussard (1798-1879) was a journalist, a businessman involved in the Paris-Rouen railway, and an economist. He was the editor of Le Journal des économistes from 1843 to 1845, a contributor to the Revue encyclopédique, and a co-editor with Eugène Daire of the Works of Turgot for the Collection des Principaux Économistes published by Guillaumin. During the Second Republic he was appointed the prefect of la Seine-Inférieure and was elected to the Council of State.
Louis Leclerc (1799-1854) was a founding member of the Free Trade Association, a member of the Société d'Économie Politique, and briefly an editor of the Journal des Économistes and the Journal d’agriculture, the director of a independent private school called "l"école néopédique” between 1836 and 1848, secretary of the Chamber of Commerce of Paris, and a member of the jury at the London Trade Exhibition in 1851. Leclerc had a special interest in agricultural economics (wine and silk production) on which he wrote many articles for the Journal des Économistes. His article in 1848 on Victor Cousin’s idea of “the self” and property rights had a big impact on Molinari. See, Louis Leclerc, “Simple observation sur le droit de propriété,” (Some Simple Observations on the Rights of Property) Journal des Économistes, vol. 21, no. 90, 15 October 1848, pp. 304-305.
Swiss by birth, he came to France to work as a land surveyor and soon moved to Paris to work as a translator of German texts. After becoming interested in economics, he and Sismondi began in 1833 a short-lived journal, La Revue mensuelle d’économie politique, which lasted only three years. One of the notable aspects of Fix’s works was his fluency in both German and English, which allowed him to write with authority for a French-speaking audience on the economics works published in those languages. In the course of his work Fix met many well-respected French political economists, such as Rossi and Blanqui; wrote several articles for Le Journal des économistes; and became the chief economics writer for the periodical Le Constitutionnel. Before he died at a young age from heart disease, he published one book, Observations sur l’état des classes ouvrières (1846).
Guillaumin (1801-1864) was a mid-19th century French classical liberal publisher who founded a publishing dynasty which lasted from 1835 to around 1910 and became the focal point for the classical liberal movement in France. Guillaumin was orphaned at the age of five and was brought up by his uncle. He came to Paris in 1819 and worked in a bookstore before eventually founding his own publishing firm in 1835. He became active in liberal politics during the 1830 revolution and made contact with the economists Adolphe Blanqui and Joseph Garnier. He became a publisher in 1835 in order to popularize and promote classical liberal economic ideas, and the firm of Guillaumin eventually became the major publishing house for liberal ideas in the mid nineteenth century. Guillaumin helped found the Journal des économistes in 1841 with Horace Say (Jean-Baptiste’s son) and Joseph Garnier. The following year he helped found the Société d’économie politique which became the main organization which brought like-minded classical liberals together for discussion and debate.
His firm published scores of books on economic issues, making its catalog a virtual who’s who of the liberal movement in France. Their 1866 catalog listed 166 separate book titles, not counting journals and other periodicals. For example, he published the works of Jean-Baptiste Say, Charles Dunoyer, Frédéric Bastiat, Gustave de Molinari and many others, including translations of works by Hugo Grotius, Adam Smith, Jeremy Bentham, John Stuart Mill, and Charles Darwin. By the mid-1840s Guillaumin's home and business had become the focal point of the classical liberal lobby in Paris which debated and published material opposed to a number of causes which they believed threatened liberty in France: statism, protectionism, socialism, militarism, and colonialism. After his death in 1864 the firm’s activities were continued by his oldest daughter Félicité, and after her death it was handed over to his youngest daughter Pauline. The firm of Guillaumin continued in one form or another from 1835 to 1910 when it was merged with the publisher Félix Alcan.
Guillaumin also published the following key journals, collections, and encyclopedias: Journal des économistes (1842–1940), L’Annuaire de l"économie politique (1844–99), the multivolume Collection des principaux économistes (1840–48), Bibliothèques des sciences morales et politiques (1857–), Dictionnaire de l’économie politique (1852) (coedited with Charles Coquelin), and Dictionnaire universel théorique et practique du commerce et de la navigation (1859-61).
Frédéric Bastiat (1801-1850) was a pivotal figure in French classical liberalism in the mid-19th century. He suddenly emerged from the south west province of Les Landes to assume leadership of the fledgling French free trade movement in 1846 which he modelled on that of Richard Cobden’s Anti-Corn Law League in England. Bastiat then turned to a brilliant career as an economic journalist, debunking the myths and misconceptions people held on protectionism in particular and government intervention in general, which he called “sophisms” or “fallacies” - Economic Sophisms. Part I (1846), Economic Sophisms. Part II (1848).
When revolution broke out in February 1848 Bastiat was elected twice to the Chamber of Deputies where he served on the powerful Finance Committee where he struggled to bring government expenditure under control. He confounded his political opponents with his consistent libertarianism: on the one hand he denounced the socialists for their economic policies, but took to the streets to prevent the military from shooting them during the riots which broke out in June 1848. In the meantime he was suffering from a debilitating throat condition (possibly throat cancer) which severely weakened him and led to his early death on Christmas Eve in 1850.
Knowing he was dying, Bastiat attempted to complete his magnum opus on economic theory, his Economic Harmonies (1850). In this work he showed the very great depth of his economic thinking and made advances which heralded the Austrian school of economics which emerged later in the century. In his final months he wrote two of his greatest essays, The Law (June 1850) which is a critique of socialism and a defense of natural law and limited government, and What is Seen and What is Not Seen (July 1850) which was a collection of essays in which he explored one of his best known and most penetrating economic insights. Bastiat to the end was an indefatigable foe of political privilege, unaccountable monarchical power, the newly emergent socialist movement, and above all, the vested interests who benefited from economic protectionism. He was a giant of 19th century classical liberalism. Other important works include Cobden and the League (1845), Property and Plunder (1848), The State (1848), Damn Money! (1849), What is Seen and What is Not Seen (1850), and The Law (1850).
Charles Coquelin (1802-1852) was one of the leading figures in the Political Economy movement in Paris before his untimely death. He was selected by the publisher Guillaumin to edit the prestigious and voluminous Dictionnaire de l’économie politique (1852) because of his erudition and near photographic memory. He also wrote dozens of articles for the Dictionnaire. Coquelin was born in Dunkirk and went to Paris in order to study law but he spent considerable time reading the classic works of political economy, developing a keen interest in business cycles after the depression of 1825-26. In 1827 he began a journal, Les Annales du Commerce (1827-28) in which he wrote on banking matters. In the early 1830s he turned to banking policy in the United States, especially in New England where there were liberal laws governing the creation of banks. Financial concerns in 1839 forced him to seek employment in the textile industry on which he wrote a number of works. In the early 1840s he wrote a series of articles for La Revue des Deux-Mondes on banking in which he toyed with the idea of the competitive issue of currencies by banks competing for business in the market. These ideas were further developed in his major book on the subject, Du Crédit et des Banques which appeared in 1848. Coquelin was also very active in the free trade movement, becoming secretary of the Association and writing articles for Bastiat’s journal Le libre-échange and later taking over the editor’s role when Bastiat had to resign because of ill health. He also wrote dozens of articles and book reviews for the Journal des économistes. During the 1848 Revolution Coquelin was active in forming a debating club, the Club de la Liberté du Travail (the Club for the Freedom of Working) which took on the socialists before it was violently broken up by opponents. He, along with Bastiat, Fonteyraud, Garnier, and Molinari, started a small revolutionary magazine written to appeal to ordinary people, Jacques Bonhomme, which lasted only a few weeks in June before it too was forced to close. Coquelin wrote on transport, the linen industry, the law governing corporations, money, credit, and banking (especially free banking of which he was probably the first serious advocate).
Léon Faucher (1803-54) was a journalist, writer, and deputy for the Marne (1847-1851). He became an journalist during the July Monarchy writing for Le Constitutionnel, and Le Courrier français, for which Molinari and Bastiat wrote, and was one of the editors of the Revue des deux mondes and the Journal des économistes. Faucher was appointed to the Académie des sciences morales et politiques in 1849 and was active in L’Association pour la liberté des échanges. During the Second Republic he was Minister of Public Works (1848) and Minister of the Interior (1848-49). Under President Louis Napoléon he was de facto head of the government (April-October 1851) but resigned rather than serve under him after his coup d’état of 2 December 1851. He wrote on prison reform, gold and silver currency, socialism, and taxation. One of his better-known works was Études sur l’Angleterre (1856).
Dupuit was an engineer and a political economist who wrote on the economics of public works. He trained at the École polytéchnique (1822) and rose to become the chief engineer of the Corps des ponts et chaussées (the Bridges and Roads Department) where he worked on the design and building of roads and the sewers of Paris. He wrote a number of books on the cost of maintaining roads, the role of tolls in financing roads, the railway monopoly, and the measurement of public utility. Dupuit also wrote several articles in the DEP, vol. 2 on "Péages” (Tolls), pp. 339-44; "Routes et chemins” (Highways and Roads), pp. 555-60; "Voies de communication” (Communication Routes), pp. 846-54. See also, Jules Dupuit, De l"influence des péages sur l"utilité des voies de communication (Paris: Guillaumin et Cie., 1849). In the article on "Péages” he comes close to developing the idea of the "Laffer Curve” where he argues that lowering the cost of the toll on a public highway would lead to an eventual increase in the overall revenue raised as a result of the increased traffic which resulted.
Ambroise Clément (1805-86) was an economist and secretary to the mayor of Saint-Étienne for many years. Clément was able to travel to Paris frequently to participate in political economy circles. In the mid 1840s he began writing on economic matters and so impressed Guillaumin that the latter asked him to assume the task of directing the publication of the important and influential Dictionnaire de l’économie politique, in 1850. Clément was a member of the Société d’économie politique from 1848, a regular writer and reviewer for the Journal des économistes, and was made a corresponding member of the Académie des sciences morales et politiques in 1872. He wrote the following works: Recherches sur les causes de l’indigence (1846); Des nouvelles Idées de réforme industrielle et en particulier du projet d’organisation du travail de M. Louis Blanc (1846); La crise économique et sociale en France et en Europe (1886); as well as an early review of Bastiat’s Economic Harmonies for the Journal des économistes (1850), in which he praised Bastiat’s style but criticized his position on population and the theory of value. Two works which deserve special note are the article on “spoliation” (plunder), “De la spoliation légale,” Journal des économistes, vol. 20, no. 83, 1er juillet 1848, which he wrote in the heat of the June Days uprising in Paris, and the two volume work on social theory which has numerous “Austrian” insights, Essai sur la science sociale. Économie politique - morale expérimentale - politique théorique (Paris: Guillaumin, 1867), 2 vols.
Michel Chevalier (1806-87) was a liberal economist and alumnus of the École polytechnique and a Minister under Napoleon III. Initially a Saint-Simonist, he was imprisoned for two years (1832-33). After a trip to the United States, he published Lettres sur l’Amérique du Nord (1836), Histoire et description des voies de communications aux Etats-Unis et des travaux d’art qui en dependent (1840-41), and Cours d’économie politique (1845–55). He was appointed to the chair of political economy at the Collège de France in 1840 and was sacked from his position in the early days of the February Revolution for his free market views. His dismissal from his teaching post during the 1848 Revolution was strongly resisted by the Political Economy Society which was able to eventually get him reinstated a few months later. He became close to Napoleon III during the Second Empire and was appointed a senator in 1860. He was an ardent free trader and was an admirer of Bastiat and Cobden and played a decisive role in the free trade treaty signed between France and England in 1860 (Chevalier was the signatory for France, while Cobden was the signatory for England).
Hortense Cheuvreux (née Girard) was married to Jean Pierre-Casimir Cheuvreux (1797-1881), who was a wealthy textile merchant. Casimir was active in liberal circles in Paris, helping to fund their activities and running an important salon, headed by Hortense, from their Paris home. People like the scientist Jean-Jacques Ampère and the politician and historian Alexis de Tocqueville attended, as did Bastiat. Casimir’s sister, Anne Cheuvreux, had married Horace Say, the son of the economist Jean-Baptiste Say, who was also a wealthy businessman who helped fund liberal activities. Like Hortense, Anne Say ran a liberal salon. Thus the two women and the Cheuvreux-Say families played an important role in liberal circles in Paris during the 1840s.
Fontenay was a member of the Société d’économie politique and an ally of Bastiat in their debates in the Société on the nature of rent. Fontenay worked with Prosper Paillottet in editing the Œeuvres complètes of Bastiat and was a regular contributor to Le Journal des économistes right up to his death. In a work published soon after Bastiat’s death in 1850, Du revenu foncier (1854), Fontenay describes himself and Bastiat as forming a distinct “French school of political economy,” tracing its roots back to Jean-Baptiste Say and including Antoine Destutt de Tracy, Charles Comte, and especially Charles Dunoyer, in contrast with the “English school” of Adam Smith, Thomas Malthus, and David Ricardo.
Louis Wolowski (1810-76) was a lawyer, politician, and economist of Polish origin. His interests lay in industrial and labor economics, free trade, and bimetallism. He was a professor of industrial law at the Conservatoire national des arts et métiers, a member of the Académie des sciences morales et politiques from 1855, serving as its president in 1866-67, and a member and president of the Société d’économie politique. His political career started in 1848, when he represented La Seine in the Constituent and Legislative Assemblies. During the 1848 Revolution he was an ardent opponent of the socialist Louis Blanc and his plans for labor organization. Wolowski continued his career as a politician in the Third Republic, where he served as a member of the Assembly and took an interest in budgetary matters. He edited the Revue de droit français et étranger and wrote articles for the Journal des économistes. Among his books are Cours de législation industrielle. De l’organisation du travail (1844) and Études d’économie politique et de statistique (1848), La question des banques (1864), La Banque d’Angleterre et les banques d’Ecosse (1867), La liberté commerciale et les résultats du traité de commerce de 1860 (1869), and L’or et l’argent (1870).
Joseph Garnier (1813-81) was a professor, journalist, politician, and activist for free trade and peace. He came to Paris in 1830 and came under the influence of Adolphe Blanqui, who introduced him to economics and eventually became his father-in-law. Garnier was a pupil, professor, and then director of the École supérieure de commerce de Paris, before being appointed the first professor of political economy at the École des ponts et chaussées in 1846. Garnier played a central role in the burgeoning free-market school of thought in the 1840s in Paris and was one of the leading exponents of Malthusian population theory. He was one of the founders of L’Association pour la liberté des échanges and the chief editor of its journal, Le Libre échange; he was active in the Congrès de la paix; he was one of the founders along with Guillaumin of the Journal des économistes, of which he became chief editor in 1846; he was one of the founders of the Société d’économie politique in 1842 and was its perpetual secretary; and he was one of the founders (with Bastiat) of the 1848 liberal broadsheet Jacques Bonhomme. Garnier was acknowledged for his considerable achievements by being nominated to join the Académie des sciences morales et politiques in 1873 and to become a senator in 1876. He was author of numerous books and articles, among which include Introduction à l’étude de l’Économie politique (1843); Traité d’économie politique (1845), Richard Cobden, les ligueurs et la ligue (1846); and Congrès des amis de la paix universelle réunis à Paris en 1849 (1850). He edited Malthus’s Essai sur le principe de population (1845); and Du principe de population (1857).
Jean-Gustave Courcelle-Seneuil (1813-1892) studied law, worked in the metallurgy business, was an editor of the Journal des Économistes, served briefly as the Director of Education in Duclerc’s government during the 1848 revolution, before seeking a kind of voluntary exile after 1851 by accepting a professorship in political economy in Santiago, Chile from 1852-1862. He returned to France in 1863, became a Conseiller d’État in 1879, and worked at the École normale supérieure de Paris from 1881-1883. In 1882 was was elected to the Academy of Moral and Political Sciences. His scholarly interests included banking and credit, numerous works on economic theory, a constitutional investigation of the impact of the French Revolution, and the translation into French of works by J.S. Mill, William Graham Sumner, and Adam Smith. See especially the Traité théorique et practique d’économie politique, 2 vols. (1856), and Études sur la science sociale (1862).
Maurice Block (1816-1901) was born in Berlin and studied at the Universities of Bonn, Heidelberg, and Tübingen from which he received his doctorate. He moved to France in the mid-1840s in order to take up a position as a statistician in the Ministry of Agriculture, Commerce, and Public Works (1844-1853) and then in the General Statistical Service (1853-1861). Block wrote mainly on agriculture, finance, and public administration during the 1860s and 1870s, before turning to the criticism of socialism in the 1890s. He was a prolific author of articles for magazines and journals such as the Revue des Deux Mondes, the Journal des Économistes, and the Journal des Débats and edited several important dictionaries and series such as the Annuaire de l’Économie politique et de la Statistique (1859-1879), the Dictionnaire de l’administration française (1855), the Dictionnaire générale de la politique (1st edition 1862-64, 2nd edition 1873), and the Dictionnaire de l’économie politique (1852-53). For the latter, Block wrote a huge number of biographies and bibliographical articles revealing his extraordinarily broad learning in political and economic matters across a number of languages. Block was elected to the Académie des sciences morales et politiques in April 1880.
Gustave de Molinari (1819-1912) was born in Belgium but spent most of his working life in Paris, becoming the leading representative of the laissez-faire school of classical liberalism in France in the second half of the nineteenth century. His liberalism was based upon the theory of natural rights (especially the right to property and individual liberty), and he advocated complete laissez-faire in economic policy and the ultra-minimal state in politics. During the 1840s he joined the Société d’économie politique and was active in the Association pour la liberté des échanges. During the 1848 revolution he vigorously opposed the rise of socialism and published shortly thereafter two rigorous defenses of individual liberty in which he pushed to its ultimate limits his opposition to all state intervention in the economy, including the state's monopoly of security. During the 1850s he contributed a number of significant articles on free trade, peace, colonization, and slavery to the Dictionnaire de l"économie politique (1852-53) before going into exile in his native Belgium to escape the authoritarian regime of Napoleon III. He became a professor of political economy at the Musée royale de l"industrie belge and published a significant treatise on political economy, Cours d'économie politique (1855), and a number of articles opposing state education. In the 1860s Molinari returned to Paris to work on the Journal des débats, becoming editor from 1871 to 1876. Toward the end of his long life Molinari was appointed editor of the leading journal of political economy in France, the Journal des économistes (1881-1909). Some of Molinari’s more important works include Les Soirées de la rue Saint-Lazare (1849), L"Évolution économique du dix-neuvième siècle: Théorie du progrès (1880), and L"Évolution politique et la révolution (1884).
Hippolyte Castille (1820-1886) was born in Montreuil-sur-Mer (département de Pas-de-Calais) and was a prolific French author who wrote popular works on the History of the Second French Republic (4 vols. 1854-56) and a multi-volume series of Portraits politiques au dix-neuvième siècle (1857-1862) which included several small volumes on classical liberal figures such as Mme de Staël, Benjamin Constant, Béranger, Lafayette, Garibaldi, Cavour, Mazzini, as well as many other individuals. He founded in 1847 a short-lived journal devoted to the importance of intellectual property, Le travail intellectuel, journal des intérêts scientifiques, littéraires et artistiques, for which Molinari wrote a number of articles. Molinari is mentioned as a “collaborator”and other leading economists were listed as “supporters” (Frédéric Bastiat, Charles Dunoyer, Horace Say, Michel Chevalier, Joseph Garnier). The journal was monthly and lasted 7 months before closing in 1848. Castille’s home on the rue Saint-Lazare (the old residence of Cardinal Fesch) was the meeting place for a small group of liberals (which included Bastiat, Molinari, Garnier, Fonteyraud, and Coquelin) which met regularly between 1844 and early 1848 to discuss political and economic matters. It was Castille’s home which supplied the name for Molinari’s book, Les Soirées de la rue Saint-Lazare (1849). Castille was also one of the founders of Bastiat’s revolutionary journal La République française in February 1848, along with Gustave de Molinari. In mid-1848 Castille gradually drifted apart from his economist friends and eventually worked on the Jacobin republican magazine La révolution démocratique et sociale edited by Charles Delescluze (1809-1871).
Henri Baudrillart (1821-1892) was a professor of political economy at the Collège de France (where he worked with Michel Chevalier), the editor of the Journal des Économiste between 1855 and 1864, was elected to the Academy of Moral and Political Sciences in 1863, and then appointed professor of political economy at the École nationale des ponts et chaussées in 1881. His major works include Manuel d’économie politique (1857) and Études de philosophie morale et de l’économie politique, 2 vols. (1858). In addition to writing articles for the Journal des Économistes, he wrote for the Constitutionnel, the Journal des Débats, and the Revue des Deux Mondes. He also contributed articles to the Dictionnaire de l’Économie Politique (1852), the Nouveau Dictionnaire d’Économie Politique (1891), and the Dictionnaire général de la Politique (1873). His scholarly interests ranged broadly over the history of economic thought, the relationship between economics and moral philosophy, educational issues, and the history and economics of French agriculture.
Frédéric Passy (1822-1912) was a politician, peace activist, and economist who served as the president of the Political Economy Society for 70 years. He was a supporter of the free trade ideas of Richard Cobden and Frédéric Bastiat and taught economics at the University of Montpellier. He was elected twice to the Chamber of Deputies (1881, 1885) where he opposed the colonial policies of Jules Ferry, the death penalty, and the legal discrimination against women. Passy was also active in the French peace movement, helping to found the Ligue internationale et permanente de la paix in 1868, and in various efforts to establish organisations to encourage international arbitration such as the Société d'arbitrage entre les Nations (1889) and the Inter-Parliamentary Union. For his efforts he received the first Nobel Peace Prize (1901, with Henri Dunant, one of the founders of the Red Cross). Passy wrote many books on economics and peace, including Mélanges économiques (1857), an important debate with Molinari on compulsory education, De l"enseignement obligatoire (1857), De la propriété intellectuelle (1859), Notice biographique sur Frédéric Bastiat (1857), and Pour la paix: notes et documents (1909).
Fonteyraud was born in Mauritius and became professor of history, geography, and political economy at the École supérieure de commerce de Paris. He was a member of the Société d’économie politique and one of the founders of the Association pour la liberté des échanges. Because of his knowledge of English he went to England in 1845 to study at first hand the progress of the Anti–Corn Law League. During the revolution of 1848, he campaigned against socialist ideas with his activity in the Club de la liberté du travail and, along with Bastiat, Coquelin, and Molinari, by writing and handing out in the streets of Paris copies of the broadside pamphlet Jacques Bonhomme. Sadly, he died very young during the cholera epidemic of August 1849. He wrote articles in La Revue britannique and Le Journal des économistes, edited and annotated the works of Ricardo in the multivolume Collection des principaux économistes, and wrote an “Introduction to Political Economy” for a popular encyclopedia in early 1849. His collected works were published posthumously as Mélanges d’économie politique, edited by J. Garnier (1853).
We have taken our information from the list compiled by Benoît Malbranque for the Institut Coppet in Paris. [169]
Of note:
See a larger version of this image [1470x360 px ].
During the period we are interested in (1837-1852 - 16 years) the firm published 360 titles at an average rate of 22.5 p.a. Some of the more important and innovative of those texts are listed below. They include texts which were in fact published as well as those which must have been in production during that time and appeared very shortly afterwards. Who decided what titles to commission and publish and what criteria they used to choose them are not known. One can only infer that Gilbert Guillaumin as owner and founder of the firm had a strong say in this editorial policy.